A Theory of Wage and Turnover Dynamics*

4 downloads 0 Views 501KB Size Report
and turnover dynamics that no single extant theory of compensation and ..... a new worker, and second, it must determine the highest outside wage offers it will ...
A Theory of Wage and Turnover Dynamics∗ Lalith Munasinghe† February 2005



I thank Pierre-Andre Chiappori, Prajit Dutta, Emanuele Gerratana, Boyan Jovanovic, TackSeung Jun, Rajiv Sethi, Paolo Siconolfi and Karl Sigman for many helpful discussions. I have also benefitted from the comments of Alp Atakan, Steve Cameron, Michael Gibbs, Leonardo Felli, Duncan Foley, Cynthia Howells, Ioannis Karatzas, Joseph Lanfranchi, Kevin Lang, James Malcomson, Jacob Mincer, Brendan O’Flaherty, Canice Prendergast, Michael Waldman, and seminar participants at the LSE, Oxford, Cambridge, UPF Barcelona, Columbia, Hunter College, Rutgers, Delaware, French Economic Association and the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. † Department of Economics, Barnard College, Columbia University, 3009 Broadway, New York, NY 10027. E-mail: [email protected]. Telephone: 212-854-5652.

i

Abstract The paper proposes a theory of wage and turnover dynamics — built on firm-specific human capital, search-and-matching, and self-enforcing wage contracts — that provides a unified explanation for a broad range of empirical observations on wage and turnover dynamics. For example, the model resolves the apparent puzzle posed by the lack of evidence of wage growth heterogeneity among jobs despite the fact that the same data show past wage growth on the job reduces turnover. The key implications of the model are as follows. First, wages increase and turnover rates decrease over the duration of an employment relationship, but the positive tenure effect on wages is predicted to be quantitatively weaker than the negative tenure effect on turnover. Second, within-job wage growth is higher and turnover is lower in high productivity growth jobs than in low productivity growth jobs. Third, the covariance of successive within-job wage increases is negative for a given productivity growth rate, whereas the same covariance, without the conditioning on the growth rate, is indeterminate.

Key words: Firm-specific human capital, Search-and-matching, Wage renegotiation, Wage dynamics, Turnover.

JEL Classification: J30, J60.

ii

1

Introduction

How wages are determined and why people move from one employment setting to another employment setting are classic questions in economics. Modern answers are based on a variety of considerations, including human capital investments, search-and-matching, incomplete information, learning, selection, and incentives. A common feature among these theories is the dynamic nature of wages and turnover. In particular, how wages are determined over the individual life cycle and employment duration, and the role of turnover in allocating workers among potential employers have taken center stage for almost a half century of labor theory. Although wage growth and its turnover ramifications are central questions in this literature, none of the extant theories can provide a compelling explanation of various and often conflicting findings on wage and turnover dynamics. This paper presents a theory that provides a unified explanation of these recently emerging findings. More specifically, the theoretical model addresses the following questions. How do wages evolve over the duration of an employment relationship? Why are worker-firm separations less likely as the employment relationship ages? Why is this latter negative tenure effect on turnover strong while the positive tenure effect on wages weak? What is the relationship between wage growth on a job and turnover? Why is serial correlation of within-job wage increases an inconclusive test of permanent differences in the rates of wage growth among jobs? The theoretical framework of this paper builds on well-known ideas. In particular, the model integrates basic elements of search-and-matching, firm-specific human capital, and self-enforcing wage contracts. The matching technology extends Jovanovic (1979a and 1979b) in the sense that each worker-firm match is characterized by an idiosyncratic productivity profile — i.e., not simply by a productivity level, but also by a match-specific growth rate of productivity, which can be interpreted as the firm-specific human capital feature of the model. Heterogeneity of such productivity profiles across all worker-firm pairs underpins a non-degenerate distribution of potential firms in the labor market. The search process of the model arises because workers have imperfect information about the location of the “best” match, and hence workers search for better alternatives while they are employed. The model retains the salient characteristic of search theory, namely, the optimal assignment of workers to firms in the presence of search frictions. The next question is: how are wages determined over the duration of an employment relationship? Since productivity increases on the job are firm-specific, time consistency dictates that firms do not have the ability to commit to future wage increases. Hence, the wage setting mechanism of the model builds on Postel-Vinay and Robin (2002) where firms have the ability to commit to fixed wage contracts, and incumbent firms respond to wage 1

offers from outside firms with counteroffers. In particular, each worker samples an outside firm from the same offer distribution in every period, and at the time of contact, the outside firm makes a take-it or leave-it fixed wage offer based on match quality. If the outside wage offer is lower than the current wage then the incumbent firm retains the worker without offering a new renegotiated wage contract, which of course implies downward wage rigidity. If the outside wage offer is higher than the “maximum-matching-wage” — i.e., the highest outside wage offer the incumbent firm is willing to match — then the worker quits and moves costlessly to the other firm. However, if the outside wage offer falls between the current wage and the maximum-matching-wage then the incumbent firm retains the worker by offering a renegotiated fixed wage contract that exactly matches the outside wage offer. This wage policy of making counteroffers is clearly time-consistent and self-enforcing, and the model generates within-job wage increases, turnover, and wage increases when workers voluntarily change jobs. The model is closed by assuming that outside wage offers are determined by a competitive process. Hence, every fixed wage offer, conditional on match quality, is such that the present value of expected profits for the firm making the offer is equal to zero. The key theoretical problems are the derivation of the expected zero-profit equilibrium wage function (on the basis of which every firm makes a wage offer) and the analysis of the properties of this wage function. The proof of existence of the equilibrium wage function is by construction: a candidate function expressed in terms of the primitives of the model — i.e. the productivity profile of the match and the distribution of such profiles — is shown to satisfy the conditions for the zero-profit equilibrium wage function. Moreover, this equilibrium wage function is also the solution to the firm’s profit maximization problem in the sense that it determines the highest outside wage offer the firm will match in every future period, which of course increases as the employment relationship ages because productivity increases on the job. The explicit characterization of the equilibrium wage also highlights the fact that the outside wage offer includes a premium that is over and above the initial productivity level of the match. This premium is equivalent to the present value of expected increases in future productivity that the worker is unable to extract in the future because of the luck of the draw. Since firms cannot commit to future wage increases in line with productivity increases, they must pay this equivalent as a compensating up-front wage premium. To preview, the main theoretical implications of the model and the intuitions for these results are fairly straightforward. First, wages increase and turnover rates decrease over the duration of an employment relationship. However, the positive tenure effect on wages is predicted to be quantitatively weaker than the negative tenure effect on turnover. These asymmetric tenure effects are the consequence of the fact that wages and turnover are not exactly determined by the same stochastic processes. The decrease in the turnover rate 2

from one period to the next is a direct function of the increase in the highest outside wage offer the firm is willing to match from one period to the next given that the outside wage offer arrives from the same distribution in every period. However, wage increases on the job are primarily governed by the independent sampling process of outside wage offers, and are not a direct function of this maximum-matching-wage because it serves only as an upper bound for a renegotiated wage contract. Since wage increases occur if and only if the outside wage offer is higher than the previous period wage and lower than the maximum-matchingwage, the expected wage increase is clearly smaller than the corresponding increase in the maximum-matching wage. Second, the mean within-job wage growth rate is higher and turnover rate is lower in high productivity growth jobs than in low productivity growth jobs. The reason is because a firm will match a higher outside wage offer for a worker in a high growth job than for a worker in a low growth job because high growth jobs generate more firm-specific rents as time on the job progresses. Since workers in both jobs sample from the same wage offer distribution, expected wage growth is higher and turnover is lower in high growth jobs than in low growth jobs. Third, the model implies that within-job wage increases in adjacent time periods will be negatively correlated for a given productivity profile, whereas the same covariance, without the conditioning, is indeterminate. This result holds despite the fact that productivity increases on the job are serially correlated by construction. Note that a within-job wage increase is given by the difference between the outside wage offer and previous period wage if the outside wage offer is higher than the previous period wage and lower than the maximummatching-wage of the incumbent firm. If the worker receives a high outside wage offer that raises the within-job wage substantially then the likelihood of receiving an even higher wage offer in the next period is relatively low. Hence, conditional on a large wage increase, the expected wage increase in the next period is small. Conversely, if the worker receives a low outside wage offer that raises within-job wages only marginally (or not at all, if the outside wage offer is less than or equal to the previous period wage), then the likelihood of receiving a wage offer in the next period that is higher than this low wage offer is relatively high. Hence, conditional on a small (or no) wage increase, the expected wage increase in the next period is large. This implies that within-job wage increases in adjacent time periods are negatively correlated. However, this same covariance computed from a population of jobs with heterogeneous productivity growth rates has an ambiguous sign. Note that the covariance of within-job wage increases in adjacent time periods is the linear association of the deviations of wage increases from their respective mean wage growth rates in adjacent time periods. With heterogeneous productivity growth rates the mean wage growth rates 3

in adjacent time periods change, and hence the covariance without conditioning on the productivity profile cannot be signed. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents various empirical findings on wage and turnover dynamics that no single extant theory of compensation and turnover can fully explain. Section 3 presents the basic model and derives the equilibrium wage function. This section concludes with a critical assessment of the modeling assumptions. Section 4 derives various model implications that are consistent with the wide array of empirical findings detailed in Section 2, and highlights some of the shortcomings of the paper. Section 5, entitled “Related Theory,” clarifies how various features of the model are related to other theories of compensation and turnover, and especially to search-and-matching models. Section 6 concludes with a short summary and discussion of further applications. The more tedious and lengthy proofs are included in an appendix.

2 2.1

Empirical Findings Tenure Effects on Wages and Turnover

Modern theories of compensation and turnover, ranging from firm specific human capital (Becker 1962) to Lazear type bonding models (Lazear 1981), are explicitly designed to show a positive relationship between wages and tenure and a negative relationship between turnover and tenure. The impetus for these earlier theoretical efforts are the widely documented empirical regularities of tenure effects on wages and turnover. Although the negative effect of tenure on turnover remains one of the most robust findings in empirical labor economics, the recent controversy about finding a positive tenure effect on wages has reignited a debate about the empirical importance of firm-specific skill investments. The early empirical support for wage increases with job seniority was based on evidence of positive cross-sectional association between seniority and earnings (e.g., Mincer and Jovanovic 1981). However, as Abraham and Farber (1987) and Altonji and Shakotko (1987) argue, this evidence is insufficient to establish that earnings increase with seniority. For instance, if high wage jobs (due to say heterogeneity of worker-firm match quality) are more likely to survive than low wage jobs, then seniority will be positively correlated with high wages even though individual wages do not rise with seniority. Using longitudinal data and corrections for likely sources of heterogeneity bias, both these studies find that the crosssectional return to tenure is largely a statistical artifact, and the true wage return to tenure is small if not negligible. In a later study Topel (1991) argues that wages do rise substantially with seniority. A subsequent reassessment by Altonji and Williams (1997) concludes that

4

wage returns to tenure across all these different estimation procedures, though positive, are modest in size. Abowd et al. (1999) using a large longitudinal French data source also find that the estimated positive wage returns to tenure are small. The current consensus is that the positive wage returns to tenure are small despite the ubiquitous fact of a strong negative tenure effect on turnover. However, none of the existing workhorse theories can adequately explain this asymmetric tenure effect on wages and turnover. For example, bonding models (Lazear 1981) and selection models (Salop and Salop 1979) imply turnover decreases with tenure precisely because of back-loaded compensation designs. Matching models also directly couple turnover decreases to wage increases. Although Becker-type sharing models of specific capital investments imply wage increases that are smaller than the underlying productivity increases, the quit rate is a direct function of the worker’s share of the costs and rewards in terms of higher future wages (Parsons 1972). Therefore, weak tenure effects on wages also imply weak tenure effects on quit rates. In another model of learning and specific skill accumulation, Felli and Harris (1996) argue that positive wage returns to tenure are a consequence of workers learning about their productivities in other firms while working in the current firm. However, in this model wage returns to tenure could be substantial and turnover is likely to increase with tenure. Hence these theories of wages and turnover do not adequately address the observation of asymmetric tenure effects on wages and turnover. By contrast, the model presented here implies not only the dual effects of tenure, like these other models, but more importantly, it implies a weak positive tenure effect on wages and a strong negative tenure effect on turnover jointly.

2.2

Tenure Effects on Turnover holding Wages Constant

A related finding to the tenure effects on wages and turnover above is the negative multivariate relationship between tenure and turnover when the wage is held constant. For example, Topel and Ward (1992) find that turnover continues to decline with seniority despite holding the wage constant. This finding is troubling for matching models since they predict that the turnover rate will increase with tenure once the wage is held constant (Mortensen 1988).1 The model in this paper, however, is consistent with this finding. Since the wage renegotiation process de-couples the wage from match value, the current wage does not necessarily reflect the increase in match value. But match value determines turnover, and hence the model predicts a negative duration effect on turnover even when the wage is held constant. 1

See also Galizzi and Lang (1998) for a more detailed description of this matching prediction. They attempt to reconcile the disparity between theory and fact by appealing to real time features of the data and identifying a countervailing factor that could reverse this matching prediction.

5

2.3

Wage Growth, Turnover, and Serial Correlation of Wage Increases

In the past two decades empirical studies using panel surveys of individual work histories and personnel records of large companies have repeatedly documented within-job wage increases, persistence of wage growth, and correlations between wage growth and turnover. Bartel and Borjas (1981) find evidence of positive correlation between completed tenure and within-job wage growth. In a later and more conclusive study Topel and Ward (1992) find that jobs offering higher wage growth are significantly less likely to end in worker-firm separations than jobs offering lower wage growth. This finding not only implies that the source of wage growth must have a firm specific component, but it also implies heterogeneity of wage growth rates among jobs. However, two studies (Topel 1991; Topel and Ward 1992), based on the time series properties of within-job wage changes, conclude that heterogeneity in permanent rates of wage growth among jobs is empirically unimportant. Hence the direct evidence seems to show that jobs do not in fact differ in their prospects for wage growth. Note that the data of the latter study are the same data that show past wage growth on a job reduces turnover. Hence the puzzle laid out in the abstract: direct evidence says that different jobs do not have different wage growth rates despite the fact that the same data show past wage growth on a job reduces turnover. Taken together Topel and Ward’s two findings — the negative correlation between wage growth and turnover, and the lack of evidence of serial correlation of wage growth — pose a challenge for accepted theory. One such theory being challenged is of course the “mismatch” theory of turnover (Jovanovic 1979a). Since the current wage is a sufficient statistic for job value, the mismatch theory is consistent with studies that find no evidence of positive serial correlation of wage growth. But the theory cannot explain the negative correlation between wage growth and turnover since it predicts that separations should decline as a function of the wage level and not as a function of wage growth.2 On the other hand, simply assuming that heterogeneity of wage growth rates can explain the negative correlation between wage growth and turnover (Munasinghe 2000), is of course open to the objection that the evidence on wage growth persistence is inconclusive. One main objective of this paper is to explain why past wage growth on a job reduces turnover and at the same time why within-job wage increases might be serially uncorrelated. Note that related studies present evidence of positive serial correlation of wage increases. For example Baker et al. (1994), using personnel records of managerial employees in a 2

Topel and Ward (1992) adopt the mismatch theory of turnover and acknowledge that their turnover result is a puzzle for this theory.

6

large firm, find evidence of positive serial correlation of wage increases in adjacent time periods. Hence the evidence on serial correlation is mixed. In a related study, Abowd et al. (1999) show evidence of substantial variation in the estimated wage tenure slopes across firms despite the fact that the estimated wage return on tenure is small. The model in this paper is consistent with this gamut of findings since it implies precisely a relatively small but heterogeneous tenure effect on wages, and indeterminacy of serial correlation of within-job wage increases. Finally, related to this issue, there is a class of wage models characterized by learning about worker ability and downward wage rigidity. The wage dynamics in these models may be consistent with the mixed evidence of serial correlation of wage increases since wages evolve as a stochastic process. For example, in Harris and Holmstrom (1982), rigid wage contracts are replaced by new wage contracts if the worker receives a better offer from the market. Chiappori et al. (1999) refer to this class of models as LDR models (for learning and downward rigidity), and derives a so-called “late-beginner property” that is common to all such models. The late-beginner property says that holding the current wage constant the future wage is negatively correlated with the past wage. As a result, the covariance of successive wage increases is positive.3 This correlation is still likely to remain positive even without conditioning on the current wage due to what Chiappori et al. call the “fast-track” effect. The fast-track effect implies that low (high) ability workers are likely to experience low (high) wage increases in successive periods, and therefore wage increases are likely to remain serially correlated. The model here, however, predicts that the covariance of successive wage increases is negative for a given productivity profile, whereas the same covariance without the conditioning is indeterminate.

2.4

Establishment Level Wages and Quit Rates

One last noteworthy finding based on an Italian data source is that conditional on their own wage, workers in establishments that pay higher wages to similar workers are less likely to quit (Galizzi and Lang 1998). Galizzi and Lang claim that the wages paid to similar workers should be interpreted as expected future wage growth. If so, this finding is consistent with the theory presented here since the model predicts lower turnover among workers with higher wage growth prospects. In fact, the model can be viewed as a formalization of the wealth maximization hypothesis proposed by Galizzi and Lang, and as an explanation of their finding. 3

Denote wt as the wage at time t then the late-beginner property says that w3 and w1 are negatively correlated, holding w2 constant. This of course implies that successive wage increases — i.e. (w3 − w2 ) and (w2 − w1 ) — are positively correlated conditional on w2 .

7

3

Model

3.1

Assumptions

Firm-specific human capital, search-and-matching, and self-enforcing wage contracts are the three basic elements of the model. This section presents a formalization and description of each of these features of the model. The key assumption is a distribution of productivity profiles across all worker-firm pairs. Each worker-firm match is characterized by an initial productivity level and a growth rate that determines future productivity on the job. Productivity increases on the job are firmspecific and this skill accumulation occurs automatically at the match-specific growth rate. The production technology of the model follows Jovanovic (1979a and 1979b): firm production functions exhibit constant returns to scale and labor is the only factor of production, and hence firm size is indeterminate. Each worker-firm pair therefore can be treated independently because each match-specific productivity profile is independent of firm size. ASSUMPTION 1. Workers face an infinite number of potential firms and each worker-firm match is characterized by a two-dimensional vector σ ≡ (p, g), where p is the initial productivity level and g > 1 is the growth rate of productivity. Hence a worker in the tth period of employment with a particular firm has pro2 ductivity g t p. Also σ ∈ Σ ⊂ R+ , where Σ is compact and φ is a nonatomic probability measure on Σ. Workers are infinitely lived and β is the common discount factor for both the worker and the firm. Furthermore Max g(σ) < β1 . σ∈Σ

Various aspects of Assumption 1 need to be clarified. In the tradition of the matching literature, there are neither good nor bad workers or firms, but only good or bad matches. Hence each worker-firm productivity profile is strictly match-specific and all workers ex ante are identical.4 Moreover, each worker faces the identical distribution φ of productivity profiles.5 The standard assumption of matching models is a non-degenerate distribution 4

Since productivity profiles are match-specific, the model implications provide a structural explanation of findings related to wage and turnover dynamics without appealing to worker or firm heterogeneity. Note that the various empirical studies cited in Section 2 have extensive controls for individual and firm level characterisitics, including a host of human capital variables such as education and experience. In addition, these empirical analyses implement various econometric procedures to correct for unobserved individual fixed effects. 5 This assumption of course would be immediate if productivity profiles are specific to firms. However, given that productivity profiles are specific to each worker-firm match, the assumption that every worker faces the same distribution of productivity profiles is stringent. Note that match-specificity of course implies firm-specificity, but not the other way round. Hence the use of the term “firm-specific” refers to match specificity and not the fact that each firm has a specific productivity profile no matter who is employed at the firm.

8

of idiosyncratic productivity levels across all worker-firm pairs. This matching idea is extended here by including a match-specific productivity growth rate as a second, human capital dimension of a worker-firm match. Typically investments in firm-specific skills are endogenously determined by the worker-firm match quality (e.g. Jovanovic 1979b; Bartel and Borjas 1981) that implies a positive correlation between p and g since the growth rate g would be endogenously determined by the level of match quality p. Assumption 1 does not impose any a priori restriction because some of the model implications rest on a less strict correlation between p and g. (See discussion in Section 4.6) A final observation is that the assumption of deterministic productivity profiles sacrifices some descriptive realism for analytical simplicity. Although there is empirical evidence that within-job wages evolve as a random walk with drift (Topel 1991), there is no such evidence on the evolution of within-job productivity. Since a deterministic productivity profile both simplifies the analysis and generates a rich set of implications for wage and turnover dynamics, a noise component is excluded from the characterization of a productivity profile. The second assumption is the existence of search frictions in the labor market. That is, search for alternative jobs is costly and hence workers do not immediately find the best match. As a consequence workers search for better jobs while they are employed. ASSUMPTION 2. At the end of every period, a worker receives an outside job offer from a firm with match quality σ e drawn randomly from Σ according to φ.

This formulation implicitly treats jobs as “inspection goods” in the tradition of Burdett (1978) and Jovanovic (1979b). That is, the productivity profile is known at the time the worker receives the outside offer. Hence there is no “learning” about match quality as in Jovanovic (1979a) or “learning” about worker ability as in Harris and Holmstrom (1982). Also since job offers are publicly observed there is no information asymmetry either. As a consequence, it is a model with complete information. The salient feature is that search is costly and hence the worker receives only a single (finite) job offer in every period. Search effort, however, is exogenous in the model as indicated by the constant offer arrival rate. The possible ramifications of endogenous search effort for the modeling results are discussed in more detail in Section 3.4.3 below. The third assumption specifies the dynamic wage setting mechanism in the presence of search frictions and productivity growth. Since productivity increases on the job are firm-specific there is no direct competition from outside firms for such skills per se. As a consequence, firms do not set wages equal to productivity at the beginning of every time period. Firms increase wages only if the worker receives a better outside wage offer. 9

ASSUMPTION 3. The outside job offer entails a zero-profit, competitive wage w(σ) : Σ −→ R+ . If this outside wage offer is higher than the worker’s current wage the incumbent firm can match this offer and retain the worker or allow the worker to costlessly move to the other firm. Moreover, firms are not allowed to renege on renegotiated wage contracts and hence wages remain constant until such time as a worker receives from another firm an offer of a higher wage.

Although firms are unable to commit to future wage increases, the initial fixed wage offer is assumed to be a competitive wage.6 Hence the wage function w(σ) is such that the present value of profits over the expected duration of employment is equal to zero. A competitive wage offer could arise, for example, if whenever a worker found a particular firm with match quality σ then the worker automatically discovers a whole cluster of identical firms. Competition among the firms within the cluster would of course remove all monopsony power, and the resulting wage offer would be an expected zero-profit wage. Hence the competitive assumption implies that lifetime rents due to the luck of the draw go to the worker. This assumption is key to the explicit derivation of the equilibrium wage function. In Section 3.4.2 the stringency of this assumption of a competitive wage offer and the robustness of the modeling results to alternative specifications are discussed in detail. The wage setting mechanism implies that firms increase wages if and only if the worker receives a better outside wage offer. Given this wage renegotiation policy the single period payoffs to the worker and firm are given as follows. Suppose at time t the worker receives a wage wt and produces gt p, where p is productivity at the time of job start. At time period t + 1 the worker receives max{wt , w(e σ )} and produces either g t+1 p if the worker remains with the incumbent firm or p(e σ ) if the worker quits and moves to the new firm with match quality σ e. The profit for the incumbent firm at time t is g t p − wt , and the profit at time period t + 1 is g t+1 p − max{wt , w(e σ )} if the firm keeps the worker, and 0 if the worker quits. The profit for the other firm at time period t + 1 is p(e σ ) − w(e σ ) if the worker quits the 7 incumbent firm and joins the new firm, and 0 otherwise. Downward wage rigidity of the model is due to the presumption of legal restrictions that prevent firms from reneging on renegotiated wage contracts (see Postel-Vinay and Robin, 6

Burdett and Coles (2003) consider a matching model where firms post more complicated wage-tenure contracts. Given risk aversion on the part of the workers, the equilibrium with homogeneous firms and workers is characterized by initial wage dispersion, as in the standard wage posting model of Burdett and Mortensen (1998), and by wages that increase smoothly with tenure at the firm. 7 The model excludes mobility costs associated with job switching. Although mobility cost, like specific capital, also creates a wedge between current and outside job values, firm-specific productivity growth generates richer wage and turnover dynamics than any alternative rendition of mobility costs.

10

2002).8 In the literature, various theoretical considerations have been expounded that lead to downward wage rigidity. For example, in Harris and Holmstrom (1982) downward wage rigidity acts as an insurance policy for workers where the economic environment is characterized by productivity risks due to learning about worker ability, and because the employer is risk neutral and the worker is risk averse. MacLeod and Malcomson (1993) show that downward wage rigidity can induce efficient investment in some circumstances of the holdup problem. Empirical evidence shows that nominal wages are indeed downwardly rigid, although real wage cuts are not uncommon (Baker et al. 1994). In another paper, Munasinghe and O’Flaherty (2005) generate real wage cuts by excluding ex post offer matching within an otherwise similar theoretical framework to the one presented here. A final observation is that the impetus for within-job wage growth is both the receipt of better outside wage offers and the wage renegotiation policy. From the worker’s perspective the source of any — i.e. within-job or between-job — wage increase is the receipt of a better outside wage offer. As a consequence, the wage at any given time is a sufficient statistic of the job value to the worker (see the formulation of job value below). Also note, since this wage setting mechanism is self-enforcing, it does not rely on reputation repercussions to be enforced like the matching models of Jovanovic (1979a and 1979b).

3.2

Existence of the Equilibrium Wage Function

Assumptions 1 through 3 describe the basic economic environment. Given this, the worker’s only decision is to quit and join the outside firm with match quality σ e if the outside wage offer w(e σ ) is greater than the current wage and the incumbent firm does not match this outside wage offer.9 The firm’s problem is two-fold: first, it must make a fixed wage offer to a new worker, and second, it must determine the highest outside wage offers it will match in all future time periods. The present value of expected profit for a particular firm depends on the wage policies chosen by other firms, since the latter affect the distribution of outside offers and hence the duration of the employment relationship. The question of existence of an equilibrium wage function w is addressed next. Given φ and some function w, the CDF of outside wage offers is determined. Write F (w0 , w) = φ(σ | w(σ) ≤ w0 ) to denote this CDF given w. Hence F (w0 , w) is the probability of getting an offer at most w0 , given φ and w. Given any w, the present expected value of 8

The fact that firms lack “committment ability” does not exclude considerations that might prevent firms from cutting wages. In this model, a firm’s lack of commitment ability only implies that it cannot credibly promise to increase wages in the future because productivity increases are firm specific. 9 Although this decision depends on the wage offers, the model here, like Harris and Holmstrom (1982), does not give the worker a major role in terms of individual choice.

11

profits to the firm from a worker with match quality σ and a current wage w is given by: ⎫ ⎧ Zw1 ⎬ ⎨ Π(σ, w, w) = p − w + βmax Π(gσ, w, w)F (w, w) + Π(gσ, w0 , w)dF (w0 , w) , w1 ⎩ ⎭ w

where gσ ≡ (gp, g) — i.e. the productivity profile starting in the next period — and w1 is the highest wage which is matched. In the above formulation the present value of profits is equal to current profits p − w, plus the present value of expected profits in the next period. The sum of the two terms within the brackets is the expected profits in the next period. The first term is expected profits in the next period if the outside wage offer is less than the current wage w since the wage for the next period then remains unchanged.10 The second term is expected profits in the next period if the outside wage offer w0 falls between the current wage w and the highest outside wage offer w1 the firm is willing to match since the next period wage is then equal to the outside wage offer. Note that this is the region of job offers where the firm matches the outside wage offer. If the outside wage offer w0 is of course greater than w1 then the firm does not match the outside wage offer, and the worker quits and moves to the other firm. Note, when a specific employment relationship terminates the firm no longer makes any profits from that worker, but the firm continues to exist. Since the production technology is constant returns to scale and firm size is indeterminate, every employment relationship can be treated independently. Profit maximization implies that the firm will set w1 — the highest outside wage offer it matches — to satisfy a zero expected-profit condition: Π(gσ, w1 , w) = 0. If the highest outside wage offer w1 the firm matches implies positive or negative expected profits then the firm is clearly not maximizing profits. For example, if w1 is such that Π(gσ, w1 , w) > 0 then the firm will allow a worker to quit for some outside wage offers greater than w1 in spite of the fact that a counteroffer would have retained the worker and yielded some positive expected profit for the firm. And conversely, if Π(gσ, w1 , w) < 0 then the firm will match some outside offers that would imply negative expected profits. From the competitive assumption that implies a zero profit condition, the initial wage offer w must be such that Π(σ, w, w) = 0. 10 Note that this downward wage rigidity is due to the assumption that it is illegal to renege on renegotiated wage contracts, and hence the firm cannot reduce next period wages in the event that a new outside wage offer is less than the wage the firm is currently paying.

12

Hence the equilibrium wage function w : Σ −→ R+ must satisfy Π(σ, w(σ), w) = 0, for all σ. If w(·) is the equilibrium wage function then the firm’s initial wage offer is w (σ) and the highest outside wage offer the firm will match at time t is w (gt σ), ∀t > 0, where gt σ ≡ (gt p, g). Hence a function w(·) such that Π(σ, w(σ), w) = 0 is the solution to the firm’s two-fold problem. Note the initial zero-profit equilibrium wage w (σ) is the actual wage paid to the worker. But the subsequent zero-profit wages over the duration of the employment relationship — that is, w (g t σ), ∀t > 0 — are simply the highest outside wages the firm would be willing to match and not the wages the firm is forced to pay the worker in every future period. The proof of existence of the equilibrium wage function w is by constructing a function and showing that it satisfies the condition Π(σ, w(σ), w) = 0, for all σ. In order to construct a candidate wage function, first denote W (σ) as “match value,” and define it as the highest present value of expected lifetime productivity of a worker with match quality σ: W (σ) = p + βE max {W (gσ), W (e σ )} ½ Z = p + β W (gσ)φ(e σ |W (e σ ) ≤ W (gσ)) +

{h σ|W (h σ )>W (gσ)}

¾ W (e σ )dφ(e σ)

The first result is given in the lemma below.

LEMMA 1. W (σ) exists and it is increasing in p and g. PROOF. See Appendix.

Match value is the present value of lifetime productivity under a policy of optimal turnover, and it is clearly an increasing function of the productivity level p and growth rate g, and hence match value increases as the employment relationship ages. Match value represents the solution to the social planner’s problem with search frictions and where each worker-firm match is characterized by an idiosyncratic productivity profile. The next proposition claims that the zero-profit equilibrium wage function can be explicitly defined in terms of current productivity and the difference in future and current match values.

13

PROPOSITION 1. Given Assumptions 1 to 3, for every σ ∈ Σ and a given φ, ) ( (W (gσ) − W (σ))φ(e σ |W (e σ ) ≤ W (σ)) R w(σ) = p + β σ ))dφ(e σ) + {hσ|W (σ) 0. (2) Turnover rates decrease with job tenure: 1 − F (w bt+1 ) < 1 − F (w bt ), ∀t ≥ 0. 22

PROOF. See Appendix.

Recall that the zero-profit equilibrium wage function w(·) — i.e. the wage function that determines the initial wage and the highest outside wage offers the firm is willing to match in subsequent time periods — is increasing in p for any given g. Hence this highest outside wage offer the firm is willing to match increases with tenure because productivity increases on the job. As a consequence the mean wage increases with tenure turnover decreases with tenure. These results are graphically illustrated in Figure 1. Note however that the mean wage increase is smaller than the corresponding increase in the highest outside wage offer the firm is willing to match since the latter is only the upper bound for a renegotiated wage contract. But the decrease in the turnover rate corresponds directly to the corresponding increase in the highest outside wage offer the firm is willing to match. The model therefore implies the standard dual tenure effects, but the positive tenure effect on wages, unlike the negative tenure effect on turnover, is attenuated due to the wage renegotiation policy. These asymmetric tenure effects are consistent with the findings of quantitatively small (and not always significant) tenure effects on wages and large (and always significant) negative tenure effects on turnover. Hence a small estimated wage return on tenure should not be interpreted as necessarily implying a diminished role for specific skill accumulation on the job. The negative tenure effect on turnover is in fact the more appropriate gauge of specific skill accumulation. The model also implies that tenure will be negatively correlated with turnover even if the current wage is held constant. Recall, turnover is determined by the highest outside wage offer the firm is willing to match but the current wage always lies somewhere between this “highest” wage and the initial zero-profit equilibrium wage. As a consequence, consider the turnover rate one period later if wages remain unchanged due to a low outside wage offer. Clearly the turnover rate falls because a period later the highest outside wage offer the firm is willing to match is higher. Hence turnover will decrease with tenure even if wages are held constant. This result is clearly consistent with the empirical observation that turnover decreases with tenure despite holding the wage constant (Topel and Ward 1992). As mentioned in Section 2, matching models are unable to reconcile this fact because they predict turnover will increase with tenure if wages are held constant.

4.2

High and Low Growth Jobs

This section introduces high and low productivity growth jobs and derives a key intermediate result that underpins various modeling results related to wage growth, turnover, and serial 23

H H correlation of wage increases. First, denote a high growth job as σ H 0 ≡ (p , g ), and a low growth job as σ L0 ≡ (pL , g L ), where g H > g L . Assume that both jobs have the same match L value at the time of job start, i.e. W (σ H 0 ) = W (σ 0 ). Hence both jobs have the same initial H L L zero-profit equilibrium wages. Since W (σ H 0 ) = V (w(σ 0 )) and V (w(σ 0 )) = W (σ 0 ), and V L is a monotonically increasing function of wages, w(σ H 0 ) = w(σ 0 ). This implies (the result is formally stated below) that the highest outside wage offer a firm is willing to match is higher in the high growth job than in the low growth job in all subsequent time periods. Let σ Jt ≡ ((g J )t pJ , g J ) for J = H and L, and for notational simplicity denote w b0H (≡ w(σ H 0 )) and w b0L (≡ w(σ L0 )) as the initial equilibrium wages, and w btH (≡ w(σ H btL (≡ w(σ Lt )) as the t )) and w highest outside wage offers a firm would match at time t, in the high and low growth jobs, respectively.

LEMMA 5. If w b0H = w b0L then w btH > w btL , ∀t > 0.

PROOF. Since match value is a function of the growth rate it follows that: L H L If W (σ H 0 ) = W (σ 0 ) then W (σ t ) > W (σ t ), ∀t > 0,

since g H > g L . The match value of the high growth job increases faster than the match value of the low growth job. Note w btH and w btL must satisfy W (σ H t ) = H L L H L V (w bt ) and W (σ t ) = V (w bt ), respectively. Since W (σ t ) > W (σ t ) and V is monotonically increasing in wages, w btH > w btL , ∀t > 0. ¥

This result underpins the various model implications related to wage growth, turnover, and serial correlation of wage increases derived in the next two subsections.

4.3

Wage Growth and Turnover

The following proposition states that the mean wage is higher and turnover is lower in the high growth job than in low growth job, holding the initial zero-profit equilibrium wage L constant — i.e. w b0H = w b0L . Denote wH t and w t as the mean wages at time t in the high and low growth job, respectively. PROPOSITION 3. (1) Mean wage is higher in the high growth job than in the L low growth job: wH t > wt , ∀t > 0. (2) Turnover rate is lower in the high growth job than in the low growth job: 1 − F (w btH ) < 1 − F (w btL ), ∀t > 0. PROOF. See Appendix.

24

Both items in Proposition 3 follow from Lemma 5. The turnover result needs the additional assumption that workers in both jobs sample outside wage offers from same distribution in every period. These results are graphically illustrated in Figure 2. Note, although both jobs have the same match value (and hence the same initial zero-profit, equilibrium wages at the time of job start), it does not imply that the expected sum of productivities in the two jobs are the same. Recall, match value refers to the present value of lifetime productivity that includes not only expected productivity in the incumbent job but also expected productivity in outside firms (due to future mobility). In the high growth job expected productivity in the current firm is larger than it is in the low growth job, holding match value constant. The important empirical corollary of Proposition 3 is that past wage growth on a job is negatively correlated with quit rates since average wage growth is higher in high growth jobs than it is in low growth jobs. This implication addresses a key finding in the literature that jobs offering higher wage growth are significantly less likely to end in worker-firm separations than jobs offering lower wage growth, holding the current wage constant (Topel and Ward, 1992). The precise finding is that in a turnover regression both the initial wage and current wage have significant positive and negative coefficient estimates, respectively. Note that on the basis of the model, the wage at time t is not a precise proxy for match value at time t, but holding the initial equilibrium wage constant, the current wage is a proxy for wage growth, and hence the current wage is positively related to match value. Similarly, holding the current wage constant, the initial wage is also a proxy, albeit negatively, for wage growth, and thus the initial wage is negatively related to match value. Hence the model is consistent with the observed findings of a negative effect of initial wages and a positive effect of current wages on turnover.

4.4

Serial Correlation of Wage Increases

Although productivity increases on the job are deterministic, within-job wage increases follow a stochastic process because firms increase wages if and only if the worker receives a better outside wage offer. As a consequence, the model implications for serial correlation of wage increases are more complex despite productivity increases that are positively correlated by assumption. More specifically, for a given productivity profile the covariance of successive wage increases is negative, whereas the same covariance without the conditioning is indeterminate. The latter result resolves the paradox on wage growth heterogeneity. For expositional convenience, consider the wage renegotiation policy in two consecutive time periods. Let w b1 be a random variable and define a second random variable as w b2 = 25

(1 + α)w b1 , where α > 0. Interpret w b1 and w b2 as the highest outside wage offers that a firm matches in the two periods immediately following employment. Denote w b0 as the initial equilibrium wage, and note w b0 < w b1 . If w b0 is a constant then sequences given by {w b0 , w b1 , w b2 } mimics various productivity profiles of equivalent match value. A higher draw from w b1 simply refers to a steeper productivity profile — i.e., to a higher g. The covariance of successive increases in the highest outside wage offers a firm is willing to match is positive by construction: Cov(w b1 − w b0 , w b2 − w b1 ) = αV ar(w b1 ) > 0.

Note the reason for this positive covariance is the assumption of a positive covariance of successive increases in the underlying productivity. Next, denote X1 and X2 as the wage offers in periods 1 and 2, respectively, from a stationary distribution. Let w1 and w2 be the observed wages in periods 1 and 2 due to the wage renegotiation process. In the first period, if X1 ≤ w b0 then w1 = w b0 and if w b0 < X1 ≤ w b1 then w1 = X1 ; in the second period, if X2 ≤ w1 then w2 = w1 and if w1 < X2 ≤ (1 + α)w b1 then w2 = X2 . If either X1 > w b1 or X2 > w b2 then such observations will not be sampled because the worker would have quit and gone to a new firm. The following proposition states the main result.

PROPOSITION 4. (1) For a given productivity profile the covariance of successive wage increases is negative: Cov(w1 − w b0 , w2 − w1 ) < 0, for a given {w b0 , w b1 , w b2 }. (2) The unconditional covariance however is indeterminate: Cov(w1 − w b0 , w2 − w1 ) T 0.

PROOF. See Appendix.

The intuition behind the first item of this proposition is that the first period wage is the lower bound for the second period wage. So if the wage increase is small in the first period then the scope for wage increase in the second period is relatively high, and vice versa. As a consequence the expected wage increase in the second period is negatively related to the first period wage increase, implying that within-job wage increases are negatively correlated for any given productivity profile. This intuition is illustrated in Figure 3. The second item of Proposition 4 may appear counter intuitive since for any given productivity profile the covariance is negative. However, if observations from high and low growth jobs are combined the covariance between first period wage increases and second period wage increases becomes indeterminate for a purely statistical reason. Note, the covariance 26

measures the linear association between the deviations of two random variables from their respective means. Since the means for first period and second period wage increases change when populations with different growth rates are combined, the covariance of successive wage increases becomes indeterminate. Figure 4 attempts to illustrate. The exact sign of this unconditional covariance for a given φ will depend on which of the following two countervailing forces dominate. The first is of course the negative correlation of successive wage increases for a given productivity profile — i.e. item (1) of Proposition 4. A lower growth rate is likely to result in a smaller negative correlation because it makes zero wage increases in successive periods more likely. Also a higher match value will tend to reduce this negative correlation because a high match value implies a lower probability of receiving a higher outside wage offer. These factors that make small or zero wage increases in successive periods more likely will tend to attenuate this negative correlation. Put simply, a productivity profile with a high growth rate or low match value will imply a stronger negative correlation of successive wage increases. The second positive effect is due to the extent of heterogeneity of productivity growth rates holding match value constant. Clearly the means of wage increases in successive periods will be positively correlated given heterogeneity of productivity growth rates. In terms of the basic elements of the model, if p and g are positively correlated then holding match value constant would imply little variation in observed growth rates, which in turn would attenuate this positive effect on the covariance of successive wage increases.15 However, if p and g are negatively correlated then holding match value constant would nevertheless generate a large variation in g, and thus a large positive effect on the unconditional covariance term. Hence the distribution of p and g will critically determine the size of this positive effect on the unconditional covariance. In conclusion, the exact sign of covariance of wage increases in successive periods without conditioning on the growth rate, will of course depend on which of these two countervailing forces dominate. To address the empirical results on serial correlation of wage increases, note one impli15

The correlation between p and g, or its equivalent counterparts, has been investigated both theoretically and empirically. As mentioned earlier, if g was endogenously determined by p like in Jovanovic (1979b) then holding match value constant would imply no variation in g at all. On the other hand, different on-the-job learning opportunities combined with equilibrium considerations could imply a negative correlation between between p and g. For example, Becker (1975) and Mincer (1993) have argued that labor mobility will lead to equalization of present values among jobs with different learning opportunities, and Hause (1980), using Swedish data, estimated a wage model that implied a negative correlation between the individual constant term and slope. These latter studies suggest a negative correlation between p and g. A similar idea can also be found in the literature on the adoption of new technologies. As Parente (1993) writes, “The firm faces a tradeoff in its choice of technologies to adopt. The more advanced the new tachnology is, the greater its productive potential, but smaller the firm’s starting level of expertise in that technology.” The comparative static exercise in this paper also implies a similar tradeoff between current productivity and growth rate of productivity.

27

cation of item (1) in Proposition 4 is that if heterogeneity of permanent wage growth rates among jobs is unimportant, as Topel and Ward (1992) claim, then the model predicts a negative covariance of successive wage increases, which they do not find in their data. The key theoretical point, however, is the indeterminacy of serial correlation of wage increases despite the fact that productivity increases are serially correlated by construction, which implies that serial correlation of wage increases is an inconclusive test of differences in permanent rates of wage growth among jobs. Hence studies that fail to find positive serial correlation of wage increases such as Topel (1991) and Topel and Ward (1992) do not necessarily present evidence against the hypothesis of heterogeneity of permanent differences in wage growth rates among jobs. More important, Propositions 3 and 4 jointly solve one of the empirical riddles that motivated the paper: past wage growth reduces turnover and yet the same data fail to show any evidence of serial correlation of wage increases. The model explains why positive serial correlation of wage increases is not a necessary implication of heterogeneity of permanent wage growth rates among jobs.

4.5

Other Implications

The search-and-matching and wage renegotiation features of the model directly imply some other well-known results related to wages and labor mobility. For example, wage increases and turnover decreases over the individual life cycle are direct implications of models with search frictions. The model presented here implies that wages increase and turnover rates decrease with labor market experience. Workers who have been in the labor market for a long time are more likely to have found better jobs with higher wages and as a consequence are less likely to turnover in the future. These patterns are widely documented in the empirical literature. On a related note, the model also predicts positive wage gains when workers change employers. Note, firms offer zero-profit equilibrium wages and workers only quit when they receive a wage offer that is higher than the maximum wage the incumbent firm is willing to match. As a result, mobility wage gains conditional on a quit — the difference in first period wages in a new firm and last period wages in the old firm — are always positive. Evidence shows that wage gains of movers are positive especially among those who “quit” their jobs (Mincer 1986). Job matching models generate equilibrium wage dispersion. Since matching with heterogeneous growth rates and wage renegotiation create more complex wage outcomes, the model here generates wage dispersion even if observed and unobserved worker and job characteristics such as tenure, experience, and match quality are held constant. The reason is

28

that wage renegotiation creates an essential indeterminacy of current wages that must lie between the equilibrium wage and the highest outside wage offers the firm is willing to match in future time periods. Hence wage dispersion is not simply a consequence of heterogeneous match quality, but it also driven by firm specific productivity growth and the policy of wage renegotiation.16 A final noteworthy implication of wage renegotiation is the cluster of observations at zero nominal within-job wage changes. If an outside wage offer is less than current wages, the next period wage remains unchanged. As a consequence, the model predicts a cluster of exactly zero nominal wage changes. McLaughlin (1994) presents evidence, from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (1976-1986), of nominal wage changes of those staying with the same employer, where the striking feature is indeed the large cluster of observations at precisely the point of zero nominal changes. Baker et al. (1994) also show that among a sample of managerial employees a significant proportion of them receive precisely zero nominal salary increases.

4.6

Some Shortcomings

Since one of the main motivations for this study is to replicate properties of individual wage and turnover data, the absence of a quantitative evaluation of the model is a limitation of the paper. In particular, the model implications for the quantitative effects of tenure on wages and turnover, and the sign of the covariance of wage increases in adjacent time periods depend crucially on the distribution of p and g among jobs As a consequence, a simulation exercise to determine some the joint distributions of p and g that could generate quantitatively sensible results is an important extension and validation of the theory elaborated in this paper. In an on-going companion paper (Gerratana and Munasinghe 2005), one clear focus is to bridge the gap between this theory and an empirical evaluation of the model. Clearly the model presented here does not address other well documented facts about wages and turnover. For example, although the evidence on mobility wage gains conditional on a quits is largely positive, there is nevertheless a substantial fraction of job-to-job changes that are associated with a wage cut, which is inconsistent with the model. A model where a firm pays a worker her marginal product in every period would indeed generate such a result. 16

These results are comparable to the results in Burdett and Coles (2003) where there is both initial wage dispersion and wage increases with tenure. They obtain these results within the context of homogeneous firms and workers, because in part what they want to explain is wage dispersion across worker who are observationally equivalent. The model presented here of course assumes heterogeneity of match quality across worker-firm pairs. But note that under this assuption workers are nonetheless observationally equivalent. For a recent and thorough survey of wage dispersion in search-theoretic models of labor markets see Rogerson et al. (2004).

29

A worker moving to a high growth job would be willing to take a wage cut in anticipation of receiving higher wages in the future. Moreover, the assumed downward wage rigidity of the model is also inconsistent with some evidence that shows within-job wage cuts are not uncommon (Baker, Gibbs and Holmstrom 1994) and negative wage returns to tenure (Ransom 1993). A final set of observations is that since the model does not assume general productivity growth, it is silent about returns to general skills or general labor market experience. Hence the vast empirical literature on estimating wage returns to experience and general skills is not addressed in this paper. Also the theory presented here only models job-to-job transitions and does not address unemployment, which is one of the central topics addressed in the search literature.

5

Related Theory

The model in this paper is closely related to the theoretical literature on search-and-matching, specific human capital, and wage renegotiation. Since Becker’s original idea of sharing costs and returns of firm specific investments as a means of providing mutual insurance to each party’s investment, the problem of wage determination has been well known (Becker 1962; Parsons 1972; Hashimoto 1981). Although the inherent inefficiency of Becker-type sharing rules was recognized from the beginning, Mortensen (1978) is the first to explicitly consider employment agreements that would induce both workers and employers to pursue efficient or joint wealth maximizing search strategies. In particular, Mortensen considers two such wage setting mechanisms: first, matching alternative offers obtained by one’s partner, and second, ex ante agreement by each party to compensate the other as a precondition for separation. He shows counteroffer matching implies an efficient turnover rule if on-the-job search is exogenous. With endogenous search effort, although the turnover rule remains efficient, each party still has an incentive to search too intensively. The second employment agreement of contingent compensation leads to both an efficient turnover rule and efficient search effort, and thus it is joint wealth maximizing. The wage setting mechanism in this paper is based on Mortensen’s idea of matching alternative offers.17 In addition, by considering only the case of exogenous worker search, 17

Since Mortensen, the idea of wage renegotiation following an outside offer has been widespread. For example, the internal wage setting mechanism of Harris and Holmstrom (1982) is based on the idea of renegotiation: firms promise to pay a rigid wage until the worker receives a better offer from the market at which point the old contract is cancelled and a new contract is made which matches the market offer. Also Malcomsom’s (1997) review article on the general issue of contracts and holdup presents various other applications of wage renegotiation.

30

the form of the employment agreement adopted here is a simpler version of Mortensen. As a consequence, the analysis of wage dynamics is more tractable, and the turnover rule implied by wage renegotiation is efficient for exactly the reasons expounded by Mortensen. The key difference with Mortensen’s seminal work is the analysis of the equilibrium wage function. Although in principle Mortensen’s framework might be general enough to allow match productivity to vary over time, this possibility is not developed into an analysis of wage determination. In particular, the absence of an equilibrium wage function implies that Mortensen’s framework cannot generate wage dynamics. In contrast, the model here by imposing structure on productivity changes on the job and by introducing a competitive setting is able to explicitly derive an equilibrium wage function. Of course, Mortensen’s objectives — to analyze efficient employment agreements in the presence of specific rents and search frictions — are different from the more immediate objectives of this paper — to develop a theory consistent with a wide range of facts related wage and turnover dynamics. In a recent work, Postel-Vinay and Robin (2002) also adopt wage renegotiation as their wage setting mechanism. As a consequence, their model and the one here share some common features including within-job wage dynamics. The key difference, apart from the fact that their model addresses unemployment, is the determination of first period equilibrium wages. In Postel-Vinay and Robin, firms pay unemployed workers only their reservation wage, and if workers are employed then firms pay only the minimum wage just sufficient to lure workers away from their incumbent employers. Thus firms collect maximal rents in contrast to the model here where all expected rents go to the worker. Further, their model allows for wage cuts when workers voluntarily move to a firm that is likely to be more aggressive in matching outside offers in the future. However, heterogeneity of firm-specific productivity growth is not a feature of Postel-Vinay and Robin’s model, and thus it is not explicitly designed to address implications related to wage growth and turnover, and serial correlation of wage increases. The introduction of productivity growth into the Mortensen type wage renegotiation framework makes this paper similar to Jovanovic (1979b) since it is one of the first theoretical articles explicitly to integrate specific human capital theory into a search-andmatching framework. Put differently, this paper can be viewed as a “Jovanovic (1979b) meets Mortensen (1978)” type model. In Jovanovic’s model, the level of match quality determines expected job duration which in turn jointly determines optimal search effort and investment in firm specific human capital. Thus match quality is positively correlated with productivity growth on the job. Jovanovic’s central result is that turnover declines with tenure. The key theoretical difference, however, is in the wage setting mechanism. In Jovanovic’s model the employer makes a wage offer to the worker that is equal to marginal 31

product. The justification for such a wage policy is based on reputation repercussions. As Jovanovic says, “employers offering wages below marginal product will acquire bad reputations and will consequently not be sampled by workers” (p. 1249, Jovanovic 1979b). But firms unable to commit to future wage increases will have to offer time consistent wage policies. The policy of wage renegotiation considered here is immune to charges of time inconsistency. The on-the-job search aspect of the model is based on imperfect information about the location of the best match as in Burdett (1978). In all adaptations of search-and-matching models, including Burdett’s, productivity level is a sufficient statistic for job value. In this paper, however, each worker-firm pair is characterized by an idiosyncratic firm-specific productivity profile, and the match value of a job increases with time on the job due to productivity growth. Embedding firm-specific productivity growth within a job matching framework generates implications for within-job wage and turnover dynamics, unlike Burdett’s model that only generates implications for wage changes due to job switches and turnover dynamics over the life cycle. This paper falls within the literature on search-theoretic equilibrium models of labor markets, and it is closely allied with various recent models of on-the-job search models such as Burdett and Mortensen (1998), Postel-Vinay and Robin (2002), and Burdett and Coles (2003), to mention only a few. All these models, like the model in this paper, are based on non-cooperative solutions to the problem of wage determination when employment relationships generate firm-specific rents. These models also generate wage dispersion even when workers and firms are homogeneous, and hence they contrast sharply with other standard models of search that is based on the Nash bargaining solution to the surplus-splitting problem.18 Note, however, that in a recent paper Shimer (2004) shows that Nash bargaining can lead to similar wage dispersion results as the wage posting model of Burdett and Mortensen (1998). Some of the best known theories of compensation and labor mobility incorporate various features of “learning” over the duration of an employment relationship. For example, Jovanovic’s (1979a) mismatch theory of turnover is based on learning about match quality. Other seminal contributions to the theory of wage dynamics — e.g. Harris and Holmstrom (1982), Waldman (1984), Ricart I Costa (1988), and Farber and Gibbons (1996) — are based on learning about worker ability. The model here does not include any such feature of learning. However, it is potentially worth considering whether learning about productivity profiles (i.e. treating a match as an experience good) or learning about unknown worker ability might lead to other potentially interesting implications. 18

See Rogerson et al. (2004) for an excellent survey of this large literature on search-theoretic models of the labor market.

32

On a related note, two recent articles by Gibbons and Waldman (1999) and Chiappori et al. (1999) have proposed models of learning about worker ability to explain a host of findings on wage and promotion dynamics. The Gibbons-Waldman model is specifically designed to explain various aspects of internal labor markets documented by Baker et al. (1994). As mentioned earlier in Section 2, Chiappori et al. derive a late-beginner property of models characterized by learning and downward wage rigidity, and they confirm various predictions related to wage and promotion dynamics using personnel data on executives of a French state-owned firm.19 Unlike the model presented here, neither of these models focus on firm level turnover. However, an interesting issue is whether promotion dynamics can be derived in the context of the model presented here by incorporating different job levels. If firm specific skills are required to move from one job level to the next higher job level, then indeed wage increases are likely to predict future promotions, an implication explicitly derived in Gibbons and Waldman. However, if promotions also signal higher general skills, such as managerial talent to competitor firms, then turnover implications following a promotion are likely to be amended. More work on the empirical relationships between promotions, wages and turnover will suggest whether the theory here might be a suitable framework to analyze internal labor market phenomena.

6

Conclusion

The paper presents a model of within-job wage and turnover dynamics based on firm-specific productivity increases on the job, search frictions, and wage renegotiation. In summary, wage increases occur because firms match outside wage offers, and on-the-job search provides the impetus for within-job wage increases. Average wage increases are higher in high growth jobs because they generate more firm specific rents. Past wage growth on a job negatively predicts quits because turnover is lower in high growth jobs than in low growth jobs. A further implication of the model is that for a given productivity profile the covariance of successive wage increases is negative, whereas the same covariance without the conditioning is indeterminate. These results are consistent with a wide range of findings related to wage and turnover dynamics. The model in this paper shows that tests of serial correlation of wage increases are 19

The model presented in this paper can also generate a result very similar to the late-beginner property: w1 is negatively related to w3 if w2 is held constant. If w1 is lower because of a low match value and w2 is relatively high because of a high outside wage offer then the predicted wage increase in the following time period is lower because the scope for future wage increase is limited (see item (1) of Proposition 3). This of course implies a lower w3 . The only difference between the late-beginner property of LDR models is that it also holds w0 constant whereas the argument here presumes that w1 is the initial zero-profit equilibrium wage.

33

inconclusive about heterogeneity of permanent rates of wage growth among jobs. The model also shows that average wage growth is higher in high growth jobs than in low growth jobs. A joint implication of these two results is that wage increases over a short duration of tenure are likely to be noisy, and hence less informative about permanent wage growth rates. It should also be noted that although longer panels provide more accurate information, they are likely to over sample high growth jobs because they are more likely to survive. Hence, variance estimates of wage growth measures from longer panels are likely to underestimate true heterogeneity of growth rates among jobs. The over sampling of high wage growth jobs also has implications for Topel’s (1991) two-step procedure for estimating returns to experience and tenure. In the first step Topel computes the within-job wage growth rate and argues that it is an unbiased estimate of the joint returns to tenure and experience. However, if high wage growth jobs are more likely to be over sampled in individual survey data then it would lead to biased estimates. This selection problem is rarely addressed in the empirical literature. Even when it is recognized as a potential source of bias, the lack of evidence of serial correlation of wage growth it put forth as a reason for its empirical irrelevance (e.g., Topel 1991; Altonji and Williams 1997). What the theory here shows is that serial correlation of wage growth is an inconclusive test of wage growth heterogeneity. Hence it is doubtful whether Topel’s first step yields an unbiased estimate of the joint returns to tenure and experience. This selection bias is further compounded by the fact that the observed wage growth on the job is an underestimate of firm specific productivity growth. Note that the wagetenure profile will be flatter on average with a policy of wage renegotiation compared to the underlying productivity profile. Thus, estimates of returns to tenure are likely to always underestimate the true returns to firm specific skills. The point is that the empirical estimates of wage returns to tenure should not be interpreted as the true returns to the acquisition of firm specific skills — the initial wage may well represent an up-front payment to the future acquisition of specific skills. In the model outside job offers act as means for workers to extract a share of employment rents. An interesting empirical implication is whether within-job wage growth rates are lower in less competitive labor markets like in small cities and rural areas. A corollary is that workers in less competitive labor markets will need to resort to alternative schemes to extract a share of rents. For example, are unions more likely to be formed in less competitive labor markets? Is the union wage premium a rent or front-loaded compensation for accumulation of firm specific skills in the future? The model here may also be consistent with observed wage adjustments over the business cycle. For example, Beaudry and DiNardo (1991) find that current wages are negatively 34

correlated with the lowest realized unemployment rate since workers began with their present employer, whereas the current unemployment rate and the unemployment rate at the time of job start have a smaller impact. Wage renegotiation implies upward wage revision due to receipt of better outside wage offers, and clearly a low unemployment rate increases the likelihood of receiving better outside wage offers. Since employment relationships have rents over and above the current wage, it is not surprising that the lowest unemployment rate over the duration of employment has a significantly larger impact on current wages. During periods of high wage offers wages will renegotiated up and during periods of less labor demand wages are more likely to be sticky.

7

Appendix

PROOF OF LEMMA 1. Since the proof follows standard dynamic programming techniques only a sketch of the proof is given. A more detailed version of the proof is available from the author. Define the operator ΓW (σ) from the space C (Σ) of continuos functions with domain Σ as: ⎧ ⎪ ⎨ σ |W (e σ ) ≤ W (gσ)) + ΓW (σ) = p + β W (gσ)φ(e ⎪ ⎩

Z

{h σ |W (h σ )>W (gσ)}

⎫ ⎪ ⎬ W (e σ )dφ(e σ) . ⎪ ⎭

The space of C (Σ) is a Banach space (see for example, Stokey and Lucas, 1989, Chapter 3). Γ : C (Σ) → C (Σ). Moreover, since ΓW (σ) is a contraction, the contraction mapping theorem implies the existence and uniqueness of W (σ) given by: ⎧ ⎫ ⎪ ⎪ Z ⎨ ⎬ σ |W (e σ ) ≤ W (gσ)) + W (σ) = p + β W (gσ)φ(e W (e σ )dφ(e σ) . ⎪ ⎪ ⎩ ⎭ {h σ |W (h σ)>W (gσ)}

The stationary policy correspondence can be represented as a preference relation over Σ (i.e. a complete order): σ Â σ 0 iff W (σ) > W (σ0 ). Simple inspection shows that W (σ) is strictly increasing in p and g.

PROOF OF LEMMA 2. To show that w(σ) is a monotone transformation of W (σ) consider σ, σ 0 ∈ Σ. Then we need to show: (1) If W (σ) = W (σ 0 ) then w(σ) = w(σ 0 ), and (2) if W (σ) > W (σ 0 ) then w(σ) > w(σ 0 ). (1) For σ, σ 0 ∈ Σ, if W (σ) = W (σ 0 ) then w(σ) = w(σ0 ). 35

First note that: ½ Z W (σ) = p + β W (gσ)φ(e σ |W (e σ ) ≤ W (gσ)) +

{h σ |W (h σ )>W (gσ)}

¾ W (e σ )dφ(e σ)

and ½ Z 0 0 0 0 σ |W (e σ ) ≤ W (g σ )) + W (σ ) = p + β W (g σ )φ(e 0

{h σ |W (h σ )>W (g 0 σ0 )}

¾ W (e σ )dφ(e σ) .

Hence W (σ) − W (σ0 ) = (p − p0 ) + βX, where X = W (gσ)φ(e σ |W (e σ ) ≤ W (gσ)) +

Z

W (e σ )dφ(e σ) Z 0 0 0 0 σ |W (e σ ) ≤ W (g σ )) − − W (g σ )φ(e {h σ |W (h σ)>W (gσ)}

W (e σ )dφ(e σ ).

{h σ |W (h σ)>W (g 0 σ0 )}

Also note since w(σ) = p + β that

(

(W (gσ) − W (σ))φ(e σ |W (e σ ) ≤ W (σ)) R σ ))dφ(e σ) + {hσ|W (σ) W (σ 0 ) then w(σ) > w(σ 0 ). Let ∆W = W (σ) − W (σ 0 ) and ∆w = w(σ) − w(σ 0 ). Note that ∆W − ∆w = β(X − Z). If X − Z < W (σ) − W (σ 0 ) then ∆W − ∆w < ∆W and hence ∆w = w(σ) − w(σ0 ) > 0, which completes the proof. First note Z X − Z = W (σ)φ(e σ |W (e σ ) ≤ W (σ)) + W (e σ )dφ(e σ) {h σ |W (h σ)>W (σ)} Z 0 0 σ |W (e σ ) ≤ W (σ )) − W (e σ )dφ(e σ ). − W (σ )φ(e {h σ|W (h σ )>W (σ0 )}

Since W (σ) > W (σ 0 ) we can simplify further and write Z 0 0 X − Z = [W (σ) − W (σ )]φ(e σ |W (e σ ) ≤ W (σ )) + σ |W (e σ ) ≤ W (σ)) ≤ [W (σ) − W (σ0 )]φ(e

{h σ |W (σ0 ) w(σ0 ).¥ 37

PROOF OF PROPOSITION 2. To show that average wages increase with tenure, first define the expected wage at time t + 1 conditional on wage wt at time t as: Z wet+1 wt+1 |wt = αwt + (1 − α) wdF (w) > wt , wt

where α = F (wt )/F (w bt+1 ). Since wt+1 |wt is greater for every possible previous period wage wt , it follows that wt+1 > wt . The turnover result follows because the highest wage the firm is willing to match increases with tenure, i.e. w bt+1 > w bt , ∀t ≥ 0, and F is a strictly increasing function.

PROOF OF PROPOSITION 3. The first item claims that the expected wage in the high growth job is higher than the expected wage in the low growth job. Since the start wage is the same in both jobs, it implies that the expected wage growth is higher in the high growth job. This proposition is proved by induction. Note that if the distribution of wages in the high growth job stochastically dominates the wage distribution in the low growth job (for time periods greater than 0), Proposition 3 follows trivially. First a lemma, to be used in the induction proof, is established. Second, stochastic dominance of the wage distribution in the high growth is proved for t = 1. Finally, stochastic dominance is assumed for t = n, and it is shown that stochastic dominance holds for t = n + 1, which then concludes the proof. Define a r.v. X from the distribution as F . Next define two further r.v.s, RL and RH , such that: RL = X if a1 < X ≤ b1 = a1 if X ≤ a1 = ∞ if X > b1 , a1 < b1 and similarly for RH : RH = X if a2 < X ≤ b2 = a2 if X ≤ a2 = ∞ if X > b2 , a2 < b2

Note further that a1 < a2 < b1 < b2 . The following lemma claims that RH stochastically dominates RL , conditional on both been finite: LEMMA. P (W L > x|W L < ∞) ≤ P (W H > x|W H < ∞), ∀x ≥ 0.

38

Proof. Define P (RL > x, RL < ∞) P (RL < ∞) P (RL > x, X ≤ b1 ) = F (b1 ) L P (R > x, X ≤ a1 ) + P (RL > x, a1 < X ≤ b1 ) = F (b1 ) P (a1 > x, X ≤ a1 ) + P (X > x, a1 < X ≤ b1 ) = (≡ GL (x)) F (b1 )

P (RL > x|RL < ∞) =

Similarly define the distribution of wages in the high wage growth job, P (RH > x|RH < ∞), as: P (a2 > x, X ≤ a2 ) + P (X > x, a2 < X ≤ b2 ) (≡ GH (x)) F (b2 ) We now show that for all x ≥ 0 the inequality in the above Lemma holds. If x ≤ a1 then GL (x) = GH (x) = 1. If a1 < x ≤ a2 then GH (x) = 1. If a2 ≤ x < b1 then GL (x) =

F (b1 ) − F (x) F (b2 ) − F (x) < = GH (x), F (b1 ) F (b2 )

since b2 > b1 . Finally if b1 ≤ x < b2 then GL (x) = 0. Hence the inequality holds for x ≥ 0, which completes the proof of the lemma. The remainder of the proof proceeds by considering wages in the first time period, and using the above lemma to show that the wage distribution in the high growth job stochastically dominates the wages in the low growth job. Then the lemma is used repeatedly to show that it holds for all time periods. Consider wages in the high and low growth jobs in the first period: W1L , and W1H , respectively. In period 0 the wages are the same in both the high and low growth jobs. Hence let w b0H = w b0L = a, and let the upper barriers: b1 = w b1L < b2 = w b1H . W1L is thus distributed as (RL |RL < ∞) and W1H as (RH |RH < ∞). Thus from the lemma, W1L is stochastically dominated by W1H . We can then take copies such that W1L = a1 < a2 = W1H . Re-define b1 = w b1L < b2 = w b1H and proceed again with the lemma to show that W2L is stochastically dominated by W2H . By continuing in this manner, we conclude that the result holds for all t. The turnover result follows directly from Lemma 5: w btH > w btL , ∀t > 0, and the fact that workers from both jobs sample outside wage offers from the same distribution. PROOF OF PROPOSITION 4. We begin with a more formal statement of the correlation between wage increases in adjacent time periods is presented. 39

R∞ 0

Let f (x) denote a probability density function on (0, ∞); f (x) ≥ 0, x ∈ (0, ∞) and f (x)dx = 1. Let Z x f (y)dy. F (x) = 0

and let F¯ (x) = 1 − F (x),where F is the underlying wage offer distribution. Let {Xn : n ≥ 1} denote an independent and identically distributed sequence of r.v.s. distributed as F : P (X ≤ x) = F (x), x ≥ 0. Let 0 < p0 < p1 < · · · denote an increasing sequence of numbers tending to ∞. Let V0 = p0 , V1 = (X1 | X1 < p1 ) and in general Vn = (Xn | Xn < pn ), n ≥ 1,

which means that Vn is an independent copy of a wage X conditional on it falling in the interval (0, pn ). Now define W0 = p0 , W1 = W0 I{V1 ≤ W0 } + V1 I{V1 > W0 } and in general Wn = Wn−1 I{Vn ≤ Wn−1 } + Vn I{Vn > Wn−1 }, n ≥ 1. Here, I{A} denotes the r.v. which is 1 if the event A occurs, and 0 if it does not. So, for example, W1 = W0 if V1 ≤ W0 and W1 = V1 if V1 > W0 . Wn thus denotes the nth renegotiated wage. The objective is to show that successive increments ∆n = Wn − Wn−1 is negatively correlated for any given F and {pn }. To be precise, consider the sign of def

Cov(∆n , ∆n+1 ) = E(∆n ∆n+1 ) − E(∆n )E(∆n+1 ). In particular, consider Cov(∆1 , ∆2 ) = Cov(W1 − p0 , W2 − W1 ), and note that by conditioning on W1 = w one can equivalently consider Cov(W1 − p0 , E(W2 − W1 |W1 )). For negative correlation, it thus suffices to show that E(W2 − W1 |W1 ) is decreasing in W1 . But W2 − W1 is conditionally independent of W1 given W1 , and only depends on a random draw X of F , so it is necessary to only consider showing for V = (X|X ≤ b) that the overshoot E(V − a; V > a) = E(V − a | V > a)P (V > a), 40

is a decreasing function of a for b = p2 . Since P (V ≤ x) = P (X ≤ x)/P (X ≤ b), x ≤ b, and b is constant throughout our analysis here, we can equivalently use X and consider the non-normalized version of the overshoot M(a) = E(X − a; a < X < b) = E(X − a | a < X < b)P (a < X < b). PROPOSITION. M 0 (a) < 0 Proof. Compute the overshoot as:

M(a) =

Z

0

=

Z

a

=

Z

∞ ∞ ∞

P (X − a > x, a < X < b)dx P (X > x, a < X < b)dx P (x < X < b)dx

a

=

Z

b

P (x < X < b)dx

a

Hence the derivative of M(a) is given by: M 0 (a) = −P (a < X < b) < 0, as was to be shown.

41

References [1] Abowd, J.M.; Kramarz, F.; Margolis, D., “High Wage Workers and High Wage Firms.” Econometrica 67 (2) (1999): 251-333. [2] Abraham, Katherine, and Farber, Henry. “Job Duration, Seniority, and Earnings.” A.E.R. 77 (June 1987): 278-297. [3] Altonji, Joseph, and Williams, N. “Do Wages Rise with Job Seniority? A Reassessment.” Working Paper no. 6010 (April 1997). Cambridge, Mass.: NBER. [4] Baker, George; Gibbs, Michael; and Holmstrom, Bengt. “The Wage Policy of a Firm.” Quarterly Journal of Economics (November 1994): 921-956. [5] Bartel, Ann, and Borjas, George. “Wage Growth and Job Turnover: An Empirical Analysis.” In Studies in Labor Markets, edited by Sherwin Rosen. Chicago: University of Chicago Press (for NBER), 1981. [6] Beaudry, Paul, and DiNardo, John. “The Effect of Implicit Contracts on the Movement of Wages Over the Business Cycle: Evidence from Micro Data.” J.P.E. 99, Issue 4 (August 1991): 665-688. [7] Becker, Gary. “Investment in Human Capital: A Theoretical Analysis.” J.P.E. 70, Issue 5, Supplement (October 1962): 9-49. [8] Burdett, Kenneth. “Theory of Employee Search: Quit rates.” A.E.R. 68 (March 1978): 212-220. [9] Burdett, Kenneth, and Coles, Melvyn. “Equilibrium Wage-Tenure Contracts.” Econometrica, Vol. 71, No. 5 (September, 2003): 1377-1404. [10] Burdett, Kenneth, and Mortensen, Dale. “Wage Differentials, Employer Size, and Unemployment.” International Economic Review, 39 (1998): 257-273. [11] Chiappori, Pierre-Andre; Salanie, Bernard; and Valentin, Julie. “Early Starters versus Late Beginners,” J.P.E. 102 (August 1999): 731-760. [12] Costa, Joan E. Ricart I. “Managerial Task Assignment and Promotions.” Econometrica 56, Issue 2 ( March 1988): 449-466. [13] Farber, Henry, and Gibbons, Robert. “Learning and Wage Dynamics.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 111, Issue 4 ( November 1996): 1007-1047. [14] Felli, Leonardo, and Harris, Christopher. “Learning, Wage Dynamics, and Firm-Specific Human Capital.” J.P.E. 104 (August 1996): 838-868.

42

[15] Galizzi, Monica, and Lang, Kevin. “Relative Wages, Wage Growth, and Quit Behavior.” Journal of Labor Economics 16, Issue 2 ( April 1998): 367-391. [16] Gerratana, Emanuele, and Munasinghe, Lalith. “Labor Markets with On-the-job Search and Wage Posting: Equilibrium Wage and Welfare Implications.” Mimeo. Department of Economics, Barnard College, Columbia University, 2005. [17] Gibbons, Robert, and Waldman, Michael. “A Theory of Wage and Promotion Dynamics in Internal Labor Markets.” Quarterly Journal of Economics (November 1999): 13211358. [18] Gibbons, Robert, and Waldman, Michael. “Enriching A Theory Of Wage And Promotion Dynamics Inside Firms.” Working Paper # 9849. Cambridge, Mass.: NBER, July 2003. [19] Harris, Milton, and Holmstrom, Bengt. “A Theory of Wage Dynamics.” Review of Economic Studies 49, Issue 3 (July 1982): 315-333. [20] Hashimoto, Masanori. “Firm-Specific Human Capital as a Shared Investment.” A.E.R. 71 (June 1981): 475-482. [21] Hause, John. “The Fine Structure of Eearnings and the On-the-Job Training Hypothesis.” Econometrica, Vol. 48, No. 4 (May 1980): 1013-1029. [22] Jovanovic, Boyan. “Job Matching and the Theory of Turnover.” J.P.E. 87 (October 1979): 972-990. (a) [23] Jovanovic, Boyan. “Firm-Specific Capital and Turnover.” J.P.E. 87 (December 1979): 1246-60. (b) [24] Lazear, Edward P. “Agency, Earnings Profile, Productivity, and Hours Restrictions.” A.E.R. 71 (September 1981): 606-20. [25] MacLeod, W. Bentley, and Malcomson, James M. “Investments, Holdup, and the Form of Market Contracts.” A.E.R. 83 (4) (September 1993): 811-837. [26] Malcomson, James M. “Contracts, Hold-Up, and Labor Markets.” Journal of Economic Literature. 35 (December 1997): 1916-1957. [27] McLaughlin, Kenneth J. “Rigid Wages?” J. Monet. Econ., 34, Issue 3 (December 1994): 383-414. [28] Mincer, Jacob. Schooling, Experience, and Earnings. New York, NBER: 1974. [29] Mincer, Jacob. “Wage Changes in Job Changes.” Research in Labor Economics, vol. 8 (1986), part A: 171-97.

43

[30] Mortensen, Dale. “Specific Capital and Labor Turnover.” Bell Journal of Economics. 9 (Autumn 1978): 572-586. [31] Mortensen, Dale. “Wages, Separations, and Job Tenure: On-the-Job Specific Training or Matching?” Journal of Labor Economics 6, Issue 4 ( October 1988): 445-471. [32] Munasinghe, Lalith. “Wage Growth and the Theory of Turnover.” Journal of Labor Economics. 18 (April 2000): 204-220. [33] Munasinghe, Lalith, and O’Flaherty, Brendan. “Specific Training Sometimes Cuts Wages but Always Cuts Turnover.” Journal of Labor Economics 23 (2), (April 2005). [34] Neal, Derek., “Industry-Specific Human Capital: Evidence from Displaced Workers.” Journal of Labor Economics 13 (4), (1995): 653-677. [35] Parente, Stephen. “Technoloy Adoption, Learning-by-Doing, and Economic Growth.” Journal of Economic Theory, 63 (1994): 346-368. [36] Parsons, Donald. “Specific Human Capital: An Application to Quit Rates and Layoff Rates.” J.P.E. 80 (November/December 1972): 1120-43. [37] Postel-Vinay, Fabien, and Robin, Jean-Marc. “The Distribution of Earnings in an Equilibrium Search Model with State-Dependent Offers and Counteroffer.” International Economic Review. 43 (4), (2002): 989-1016. [38] Rogerson, Richard; Shimer, Robert; and Wright, Randall. “Search-Theoretic Models of the Labor Market: A Survey.” Mimeo, 2004. [39] Rosen, Sherwin. “Learning and Experience in the Labor Market.” Journal of Human Resources. 7 (Summer 1972): 326-42. [40] Shimer, Robert. “On-the-Job Search, Bargaining, and Wage Dispersion.” Mimeo, University of Chicago, 2004. [41] Stokey, Nancy, and Lucas, Robert. Recursive Methods in Economic Dynamics. Harvard University Press: 1989. [42] Topel, Robert. “Specific Capital, Mobility, and Wages: Wages Rise with Job Seniority.” J.P.E. 9 (1991): 145-176. [43] Topel, Robert, and Ward, Michael P. “Job Mobility and the Careers of Young Men.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. (May 1992): 145-176. [44] Waldman, Michael. “Worker Allocation, Hierarchies and the Wage Distribution.” The Review of Economic Studies 51, Issue 1 ( January 1984): 95-109. [45] Weiss, Yoram. “Learning by Doing and Occupational Specialization.” Journal of Economic Theory. 3 (1971): 189-198. 44

Figure 1 Basic Model

Wages Quit Region

l1 w

lt w

Wage Renegotiation Region

pt

wt

w1 l0 w

p0

1

Tenure

Figure 2 High versus low growth jobs

Wages H l wt

H l wτ

L l wt

l τL w

ptH H

ptL H

l0 w

τ p0L

p0H H

Tenure

Figure 3 For a given productivity profile covariance of successive wage increases is negative

Wages

lt w

l2 w

l1 w

l0 w 1

2 Tenure

Figure 4 Unconditional covariance of successive wage increases is indeterminate

∆ w2 H

L

∆ w1