An Empirical Approach

4 downloads 182 Views 241KB Size Report
that in the cross-sectional analysis the stock market prices the skewness, which exhibits a positive sign ... Keywords: CAPM, Higher Moment CAPM, Athens Stock Market ..... “Applied Economic Forecasting,” North-Holland, Amsterdam. Zarowin ...
Messis, Iatridis, and Blanas, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 60-75

60

CAPM and the Efficacy of Higher Moment CAPM in the Athens Stock Market: An Empirical Approach Petros Messis*, George Iatridis**, and George Blanas* Technological Institute of Larissa* and University of Thessaly**

Abstract This paper uses the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) and the higher moment CAPM to estimate the financial performance of securities traded on the Athens Stock Exchange. There is statistically significant evidence that the higher moment CAPM is more efficient, while the differences between the models are statistically significant. The two models are tested for a five-year period from 2001 to 2005 using monthly data. It is shown that in the cross-sectional analysis the stock market prices the skewness, which exhibits a positive sign suggesting that investors may have a preference for positive skewness in their portfolios. With respect to systematic variance and systematic kurtosis, although it seems that investors are compensated with higher return for bearing the above risks, this relationship seems not to be significant in the cross-sectional context. Keywords: CAPM, Higher Moment CAPM, Athens Stock Market JEL Classification: G11, G12

1. Introduction The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) developed by Sharpe (1964) and Lintner (1965) suggests that the only relevant financial risk measure is the beta coefficient, which reflects the non-diversifiable/ systematic risk, and that a positive trade-off between beta and expected returns should exist. The model is still widely used and has also been used for the estimation of the cost of capital and the performance of managed funds (Fletcher, 2000; Tang and Shum, 2003; Fama and French, 2004; Perold, 2004). The literature demonstrates that, except for the market risk, other risk factors that explain the financial performance of stock returns relate to firm ‘fundamental’ variables (Harvey and Siddique, 2000). These variables include size, book-to-market value, earnings to price ratio, etc., and account for a sizeable portion of the cross-sectional variation in expected returns. The CAPM is based on the assumption that investors’ goal is to minimise the variance and maximise the expected return of their portfolios (Athayde and Flores, 1999). This paper tests whether the introduction of higher moments (i.e. skewness and kurtosis) into the CAPM, along with variance, is also important in explaining the expected stock returns. The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 presents the literature review, Section 3 refers to methodology and data description, Section 4 shows the empirical results, and Section 5 concludes the paper.

Messis, Iatridis, and Blanas, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 60-75

61

2. Literature Review Fama and MacBeth (1973) first tested the validity of the CAPM, finding that on average a positive trade off exists between return and risk. However, later studies, such as Jegadeesh (1992) and Fama and French (1996), express some doubts with regard to the validity of betas as risk measures, since their evidence suggests that betas are not always significantly related to returns. In the attempt to interpret the behaviour of stock returns, the literature presents tests of measures that are proposed as alternatives to the single market premium factor suggested by the CAPM. Banz (1981) finds that the size effect has a strong impact on stock returns, indicating that smaller firms have higher returns and thus higher betas. Similar findings are obtained by Zarowin (1990), Fama and French (1992) and Daniel and Titman (1997). Measures, such as book to market value and earnings to price ratio, appear to significantly influence the stock returns (Berk, 1995; Fama and French, 1996). Stocks with high such ratios tend to have higher returns than stocks with low such ratios. Similar results have been reported by Chan et al (1991) for the Japanese market and by Levis and Liodakis (2001) for the UK market. Liquidity also appears to influence the expected stock returns as explained by Jacoby et al (2000). Another form of the CAPM is the Consumption CAPM (CCAPM), which measures the risk of a security by the covariance of its return with per capita consumption (Lucas, 1978; Breeden, 1979). This model is tested against the CAPM for the Taiwanese stock market, where it appears that the CAPM exhibits better performance in terms of R2 in explaining the stock returns (Chen, 2003). However, Mankiw and Sharpino (1986) and Kocherlakota (1996) suggest that the consumption beta may offer a better measure of risk. An extension of the CAPM is the higher moment CAPM, which introduces the figures of skewness and kurtosis into the model. The systematic risk attempts to explain the variance of stock returns. There is evidence, however, that the distributions of returns cannot be adequately described only by mean and variance (Harvey and Siddique, 2000). Harvey and Siddique (2000) incorporate the figure of co-skewness in the CAPM and find that it is a statistically significant measure of risk, as also reported by Kraus and Litzenberger (1976). Other studies that incorporate the co-skewness in the CAPM for the valuation of stock returns are these of Rubinstein (1973) and Ingersoll (1975). Fang and Lai (1997) introduce not only the systematic skewness but also the systematic kurtosis suggesting that the expected excess rate of return is related with these two measures of risk. The same results are also reported by Friend and Westerfield (1980) for the US market, in contrast to these of Hung et al (2004) for the UK stock market that found that the betas of the extended CAPM are weaker than the market beta itself. 3. Methodology and Data 3.1 CAPM and Higher Moment CAPM The Modern Portfolio Theory, which was first introduced by Markowitz (1952), is based on that investors are looking for assets in terms of the distributions of returns, and that they tend to have an aversion to risk, satisfying the following conditions (see Alexander, 2002):

Messis, Iatridis, and Blanas, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 60-75

62

∂U / ∂μ > 0, ∂U / ∂σ < 0; ∂ 2U / ∂μ 2 < 0, ∂ 2U / ∂σ 2 < 0 The CAPM specifies the relationship between risk and return as follows: E ( Ri ) − R f = where

E ( Rm ) − R f

σ m2

cov im

(1)

E ( Ri ) − R f is the market risk premium, which is the difference between the

expected return of security i and a risk free rate (e.g. Treasury bills), cov im is the covariance of security i with the market return, and

σ m2 is the variance of the market return. Equation (1) can be rearranged and take the following shape leading to the Ordinary Least Square (OLS) empirical calculation of the beta coefficient. E ( Ri ) − R f = β i (E ( Rm ) − R f )

(2)

where β i = Cov( Ri , Rm ) / Var ( Rm ) is the systematic variance of asset i (see Fang and Lai, 1997). Following the introduction of higher moments, such as systematic skewness and systematic kurtosis, into the CAPM, the model takes the following shape (see Hung et al, 2004):

Rit − R ft = α i + β i ( Rmt − R ft ) + γ i ( Rmt − R ft ) 2 + δ i ( Rmt − R ft ) 3

(3)

where the coefficient β ι is the same as above, the systematic skewness, γ ι , and the systematic kurtosis, δι , are as follows (see Fang and Lai, 1997):

γ i = Cov( Ri , Rm2 ) / E[( Rm − E ( Rm ))3 ], δ i = Cov( Ri , Rm3 ) / E[( Rm − E ( Rm )) 4 ] The literature shows that investors tend to prefer securities that are right-skewed or portfolios that are left-skewed (Harvey and Siddique, 2000). Investors tend to have negative preference to variance1 and kurtosis, demanding a higher return for bearing such risks (Arditti, 1967; Fang and Lai, 1997). Following Fang and Lai (1997) and Tang and Shum (2003), this study tests the following hypotheses: H1:

There is unrestricted borrowing and lending at a unique risk free rate (SharpeLintner hypothesis). This implies that E (γ 0t ) = 0 in equation (4). Rit − R f = γ 0t + γ 1t β i + γ 2t SKWi + γ 3t KURi + e it

(4)

Messis, Iatridis, and Blanas, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 60-75

H2:

The risk premium is positive and equal to the average excess return of the market portfolio. This means that E (γ 1t ) = E ( Rmt ) > 0 in equation (5). Rit − R f = γ 0t + γ 1t β i + e it

H3:

(5)

The distribution of asset returns is symmetrical, while skewness is (not) priced in equation (6): Rit − R f = γ 0t + γ 1t β i + γ 2t SKWi + e it

H4:

63

(6)

The distribution of asset returns is symmetrical, while kurtosis is (not) priced in equation (7): Rit − R f = γ 0t + γ 1t β i + γ 3t KURi + e it

(7)

The hypotheses above are investigated by firstly obtaining the beta coefficients from the OLS regression, and secondly regressing the estimated beta coefficients against the average excess returns of the period under consideration.2 3.2 The Data The dataset used in the study consists of 17 securities, which are traded on the Athens Stock Exchange and come from three different sectors, i.e. banks, furniture and machinery. The study uses monthly data, while the period under analysis is a five-year period from January 2001 to December 2005 (see Dimson and Marsh, 1983). The rate of return for each security, ri, is calculated as ri = ( Pt − Pt −1 ) / Pt −1 (Lo and MacKinlay, 1988). The risk free asset used in the model is a 3-year Treasury bill. The security prices and the risk free rate were obtained from DataStream. For the analysis of data and the estimation of parameters, individual securities are used rather than portfolios (see Kim, 1995; Kaplanski, 2004). The summary statistics with regard to individual securities for the entire sample period are presented in Table 1. From Table 1, it is clear that the minimum return ranges from –15.59% to –57.24%, while the maximum return ranges from 20.30% to 56.25%. The average returns vary from –1.78% to 1.60%. Excess kurtosis can be as high as 10.35, ranging from 0.194 to 10.35. The skewness ranges from –0.767 to 2.42. Table 1 also refers to the Sharpe ratio, which is a measure of security performance (Leland, 1999). The highest performance according to the Sharpe ratio is 12.10%, while the lowest is –11.94%. The normality of return has been tested using the Jarque-Bera (JB) criterion. This test follows the χ2 distribution under the null hypothesis of normality and 2 degrees of freedom. The 5% critical value for χ2 is 5.99, which shows that 8 out of 17 securities do not follow the normal distribution (see Groenewold and Fraser, 1997). For the stationarity of the time series data, the study has used the Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test. All time series data were found to be stationary.

Messis, Iatridis, and Blanas, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 60-75

64

4. Empirical Results 4.1 CAPM and Higher Moment CAPM The first step for testing the hypotheses and comparing the single factor CAPM with the higher moment CAPM is to obtain the beta coefficients after applying the OLS method on equation (2). Table 2 reports the beta coefficients. The econometric restriction is that in a time series regression of the excess return ( E ( Ri ) − R f ) on the market excess return ( E ( Rm ) − R f ), the intercept should be zero and the betas should be statistically significant. From Table 2, it is obvious that all beta coefficients are statistically significant at 1% level. The betas range from 0.756 to 1.975, while the adj. R2 4 ranges from a low of 0.148 to a high of 0.742. Table 3 presents the results of the cross-sectional regression and describes the relationship between beta and return. Hypothesis H1 implies that γ 0 = R f . This coefficient, i.e. γ0, is not significantly different from zero and is consistent with the Sharpe-Lintner hypothesis. With respect to the risk premium and hypothesis H2, Table 3 shows that the coefficient γ1 is positive but not statistically significant. Before comparing the higher moment CAPM with the one factor CAPM, the higher moment beta coefficients should be estimated. Table 4 presents the results that come from the application of the OLS method on equation (3). With respect to hypothesis H3 and the introduction of skewness in the model, Table 5 shows that skewness is positively related to returns and has the right positive sign as opposed to market skewness for the underlying period (i.e. -0.314 in Table 1). This relationship is statistically significant at 10% level. The same results are also reported by Tang and Shum (2003), indicating that risk averse investors tend to prefer odd statistical moments, such as mean and skewness, and dislike even statistical moments, such as variance and kurtosis (see Scott and Horvath, 1980). The skewness is priced by the market, the adj. R2 is higher when skewness is introduced, and thus, this model exhibits better performance (see Groenewold and Fraser, 1997). Hypothesis H4 relates to kurtosis and whether it is priced by the market. The results are depicted in Table 6, which shows that the expected positive sign for the market premium exists, although it is not statistically significant. With regard to kurtosis, there is an insignificant negative regression coefficient, which contradicts the expectation on the relationship between kurtosis and returns for risk-averse investors, who would expect to get higher returns for higher kurtosis. Similar results are found by Tang and Shum (2003) when weekly returns are employed. The results are not better compared to the single factor CAPM in terms of adj. R2, while the kurtosis does not appear to be priced by the market. The results of the regression based on equation (3), including beta, skewness and kurtosis, are presented in Table 7. Table 7 indicates that the market demands higher returns for bearing variance and kurtosis, while an insignificantly negative relationship exists between stock returns and skewness (Fang and Lai, 1997). This relationship would be expected to be positive, as shown in Table 5, which referred to the higher moment CAPM including only market risk and skewness. Table 8 presents the significant beta coefficients after applying the OLS regression on individual securities and omitting the insignificant factors one at a time. Table 8 shows that 8 out of 17 securities have statistically significant coefficients. In particular, skewness is

Messis, Iatridis, and Blanas, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 60-75

65

statistically significant in 7 cases, while kurtosis in 5 cases. Three securities appear to be influenced by both skewness and kurtosis. 4.2 Comparing the Models The Theil’s U2 test (1966) is used for testing the single model CAPM with the higher moment CAPM. This test has also been used by Bower et al (1984) and Sun and Zhang (2001). This model uses the return divided by the test period (here 60 months) as the predicted return for each month. The Theil’s U2 test is the sum of the squared forecasting errors for each model divided by the sum of the squared forecasting errors of the naïve model. The test is defined as follows:

∑ (R − R ) = ∑ (R − R ) 60

U

2 i

t =1

mod el i ,t

i ,t



60

t =1

i ,t

i

2

2

(i = 1, 2,…, 17) where Ri ,t is the historical return for asset i in month t, el Rimod is the forecast return for asset i in month t according to CAPM and the higher ,t moment CAPM, and −

R i is the monthly average historical return for asset i over the examined period.

The smaller the ratio, the better the model forecast is relative to the naïve model. A ratio with a value greater than one would indicate the inappropriateness and inadequacy of the model. The results are depicted in Table 9. The higher moment CAPM appears to predict better in all cases. The ratio ranges from a low of 0.258 to a high of 0.620, while in one case (i.e. 0.555) both models predict the same. Table 10 shows that the difference between the two models is statistically significant at 5% level, indicating that the higher moment CAPM gives a better forecasting ability over the CAPM. The mean of the Theil’s U2 test is almost by 6% lower for the higher moment CAPM. 5. Conclusions This paper examines the efficacy of the higher moment CAPM as opposed to the single factor CAPM, and seeks to explain the relationship between expected return and risk. The higher moment CAPM incorporates skewness and kurtosis together with variance into the model. The skewness and kurtosis cannot be diversified by increasing the size of portfolios. Hence, they are important in security valuation. Thus, investors care not only for variance, but also for kurtosis demanding higher returns on risky assets, while they are willing to accept a lower (higher) return when the skewness of the market portfolio is positive (negative) (see Fang and Lai, 1997). The study shows that in the cross-sectional analysis the stock market prices the skewness, which carries a positive sign suggesting that investors may have a preference for positive skewness in their portfolios. Comparing the single factor CAPM with the higher moment CAPM, including skewness as an additional risk factor in the cross-sectional context, it has been found that the latter is better in terms of adjusted R2. Also, there is evidence that the

Messis, Iatridis, and Blanas, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 60-75

66

higher moment CAPM is significantly better when using the Theil’s U2 test. The higher moment CAPM gives a lower and statistically significant mean under the Theil’s U2 statistic than the single CAPM. The implications of the study show that there may be additional factors other than the market risk that affect stock returns. For example, the Arbitrage Pricing Theory includes in the regression equation macroeconomic explanatory variables, such as inflation, exchange rates, interest rates, etc. The Fama and French three-factor model uses proxies for size and growth together with the market risk. The identification and analysis of such factors is imperative and may be subject to future research. Endnotes 1. Arditti (1967) has shown that a typical investor who is risk averse tends to exhibit aversion to variance and preference to positive skewness. 2. The study has accounted for heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation as well as for multicollinearity, and reports that the results are not distorted or biased by such effects. 3. The Jarque-Bera test is given as follows: JB= N

⎡S 2 ( K − 3) 2 ⎤ + ⎢ ⎥ 24 ⎣ 6 ⎦

, where S is skewness

and K is kurtosis. 4. The adj. R2 is defined as:

R

2

= 1− (

⎡ S . D .( e ) ⎤ T −1 ) T − i − 1 ⎢⎣ S . D .( ER ) ⎥⎦

2

.

References Arditti, F. 1967. “Risk and the Required Return on Equity,” Journal of Finance, 22(1), 1936. Athayde, G. and R. Flores. 1999. “Introducing Higher Moments in the CAPM: Some Basic Ideas,” Economics Working Papers, 362, Graduate School of Economics, Getulio Vargas Foundation, Brazil. Banz, R.W. 1981. “The Relation Between Return and Market Value of Common Stocks,” Journal of Financial Economics, 9(1), 3-18. Berk, J. 1995. “A Critique of Size Related Anomalies,” Review of Financial Studies, 8(2), 275-286. Bower, D.H., Bower, R.S. & Logue, D.E. 1984. “Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Utility Stock Returns,” Journal of Finance, 39(4), 1041-1054. Breeden, D.T. 1979. “An Intertemporal Asset Pricing Model with Stochastic Consumption and Investment Opportunities,” Journal of Financial Economics, 7(3), 265-296. Chan, L.K., Y. Hamao, and J. Lakonishok. 1991. “Fundamentals and Stock Returns in Japan,” Journal of Finance, 46(5), 1467-1484.

Messis, Iatridis, and Blanas, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 60-75

67

Chen, H. C. 2003. “Risk and Return: CAPM and CCAPM,” The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 43(2), 369-393. Daniel, K. and S. Titman. 1997. “Evidence on the Characteristics of Cross Sectional Variation in Stock Returns,” Journal of Finance, 52(1), 1-33. Dimson, E. and P. R. Marsh. 1983. “The Stability of UK Risk Measures and the Problem of Thin Trading,” Journal of Finance, 38(3), 753-783. Fama, E. and K. French. 1992. “The Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns,” Journal of Finance, 47(2), 427-465. Fama, E. and K. French. 1996. “Multifactor Explanations of Asset Pricing Anomalies,” Journal of Finance, 51(1), 55-84. Fama, E. and K. French. 2004. “The Capital Asset Pricing Model: Theory and Evidence,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(3), 25-46. Fama, R. and J. MacBeth. 1973. “Risk, Return and Equilibrium: Empirical Tests,” Journal of Political Economy, 81(3), 607-636. Fang, H. and T. Lai. 1997. “Co-Kurtosis and Capital Asset Pricing,” The Financial Review, 32(2), 293-307. Fletcher, J. 2000. “On the Conditional Relationship Between Beta and Return in International Stock Returns,” International Review of Financial Analysis, 9(3), 235-245. Friend, I. and R. Westerfield. 1980. “Co-Skewness and Capital Asset Pricing,” The Journal of Finance, 35(4), 897-913. Groenewold, N. and P. Fraser. 1997. “Share Prices and Macroeconomic Factors,” Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 24(9) 1367-1383. Harvey, C. and A. Siddique. 2000. “Conditional Skewness in Asset Pricing Tests,” Journal of Finance, 55(3), 1263-1295. Hung, D., M. Shackleton, and X. Xu. 2004. “CAPM, Higher Co-Moment and Factor Models of UK Stock Returns,” Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 31(1-2), 87-112. Ingersoll, J. 1975. “Multidimensional Security Pricing,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 10(5), 785-798. Jacoby, G., D. Fowler, and A. Gottesman. 2000. “The Capital Asset Pricing Model and the Liquidity Effect: A Theoretical Approach,” Journal of Financial Markets, 3(1), 69-81. Jegadeesh, N. 1992. “Does Market Risk Really Explain the Size Effect?” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 27(3), 337-351.

Messis, Iatridis, and Blanas, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 60-75

68

Kaplanski, G. 2004. “Traditional Beta, Downside Risk Beta and Market Risk Premiums,” The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 44(5), 636-653. Kim, D. 1995. “The Errors in Variables Problem in the Cross Section of Expected Stock Returns,” Journal of Finance, 50(5), 1605-1634. Kocherlakota, N. R. 1996. “The Equity Premium: It’s a Puzzle,” Journal of Economic Literature, 34(1), 42-71. Kraus, A. and R. Litzenberger. 1976. “Skewness Preference and the Valuation of Risk Assets,” The Journal of Finance, 31(4), 1085-1100. Leland, H. 1999. “Beyond Mean-Variance: Performance Measurement in a NonSymmetrical World,” Financial Analysts Journal, 54 (January/February), 27-35. Levis, M. and M. Liodakis. 2001. “Contrarian Strategies and Investor Expectations: The U.K. Evidence,” Financial Analysts Journal, 57(5), 43-56. Lintner, J. 1965. “The Valuation of Risk Assets and the Selection of Risky Investments in Stock Portfolios and Capital Budget,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 47(1), 13-37. Lo, A. and C. MacKinlay. 1988. “Stock Prices Do Not Follow Random Walks: Evidence from a Simple Specification Test,” Review of Financial Studies, 1(1), 41-66. Lucas, R. E. 1978. “Asset Prices in an Exchange Economy,” Econometrica, 46(6), 14291445. Mankiw, N. and M. Sharpino. 1986. “Risk and Return: Consumption Beta versus Market Beta,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 68(3), 452-459. Markowitz, H. 1952. “Portfolio Selection,” Journal of Finance, 7 (1), 77-91. Perold, A. 2004. “The Capital Asset Pricing Model,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18 (3), 3-24. Rubinstein, M. 1973. “The Fundamental Theorem of Parameter Preference and Security Valuation.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 8(1), 61-69. Scott, R. and P. Horvath. 1980. “On the Direction of Preference for Moments of Higher Order than the Variance,” Journal of Finance, 35(4), 915-919. Sharpe, W. F. 1964. “Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Conditions of Risk,” Journal of Finance, 19(3), 425-442. Sun, C. and D. Zhang. 2001. “Assessing the Financial Performance of Forestry-Related Investment Vehicles: Capital Asset Pricing Model vs. Arbitrage Pricing Theory,” American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 83(3), 617-628.

Messis, Iatridis, and Blanas, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 60-75

69

Tang, G. and W. Shum. 2003. “The Conditional Relationship Between Beta and Returns: Recent Evidence from International Stock Markets,” International Business Review, 12(1), 109-126. Theil, H. 1966. “Applied Economic Forecasting,” North-Holland, Amsterdam. Zarowin, P. 1990. “Size, Seasonality, and Stock Market Overreaction,” Journal of Finance and Quantitative Analysis, 25(1), 113-125.

Messis, Iatridis, and Blanas, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 60-75

70

Table 1. Summary Statistics Return Mean

Min

Max

Std. Dev.

Skewness

Excess Kurtosis

JarqueBera test

P-value

Sharpe ratio

0.42%

-19.40%

15.28%

6.72%

-0.314

0.327

1.23

0.538

6.76%

Alpha

-0.081%

-22.72%

24.89%

10.05%

0.141

0.194

0.29

0.864

-0.41%

Agrotiki

-0.14%

-50.50%

32.87%

12.57%

-0.27

4.17

43.5

0

-0.81%

Aspis

-0.68%

-39.00%

25.00%

11.63%

-0.403

1.29

5.71

0.057

-5.42%

Attiki

1.18%

-48.80%

52.14%

16.92%

0.307

1.518

6.594

0.036

7.19%

Geniki

-0.64%

-35.55%

38.17%

13.98%

0.362

0.434

1.75

0.42

1.80%

Asset Market Index ASE index (GI) Banks

Egnatia

0.15%

-23.83%

38.42%

12.96%

0.775

0.952

8.136

0.017

1.47%

Ethniki

0.52%

-27.50%

38.92%

11.78%

0.217

1.136

3.63

0.162

4.74%

Ellados

0.87%

-19.45%

55.50%

10.81%

2.42

10.35

321.38

0

8.42%

Emporiki

-0.12%

-29.06%

39.02%

13.40%

0.355

0.31

1.48

0.476

-0.62%

Peireos

0.78%

-33.39%

20.30%

9.77%

-0.656

1.19

7.73

0.02

8.31%

Kiprou

0.21%

-19.82%

28.28%

9.82%

0.474

0.768

3.66

0.16

2.54%

Eurobank

0.71%

-15.59%

24.12%

8.10%

0.592

0.324

3.71

0.156

9.09% -11.94%

Furniture Dromeas

-1.78%

-57.24%

36.71%

14.34%

-0.767

3.099

29.41

0

Sato

0.80%

-36.79%

56.25%

17.55%

0.798

0.807

7.877

0.019

4.79%

Varagis

-0.07%

-32.96%

48.78%

14.70%

0.437

0.815

3.518

0.172

-0.22%

Frigoglass

1.60%

-31.25%

40.00%

13.51%

0.429

1.25

5.656

0.049

12.10%

Kleeman

0.58%

-32.20%

39.30%

11.89%

0.687

2.155

16.07

0

5.18%

Machinery

The numbers in bold show normality according to the Jarque-Bera test3 at 5% level.

Messis, Iatridis, and Blanas, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 60-75

Table 2. Estimation of Beta Coefficients of Eq. (2) Using OLS Asset Banks Alpha Agrotiki Aspis Attiki Egnatia Ellados Emporiki Ethniki Eurobank Geniki Kiprou Peireos

α0

Adj. R2

β

-0.006 (-0.84) -0.004 (-0.29) -0.011 (-1.006) 0.005 (0.289) -0.005 (-0.52) 0.0049 (0.423) -0.008 (-0.79) -0.0013 (-0.166) 0.002 (0.471) -0.012 (-0.97) -0.002 (-0.267) 0.002 (0.37)

1.261 (11.79) *** 0.756 (3.33) *** 1.142 (6.65) *** 1.546 (6.02) *** 1.549 (10.47) *** 0.893 (5.31) *** 1.586 (10.21) *** 1.502 (12.96) *** 0.993 (10.92) *** 1.459 (7.60) *** 1.067 (8.05) *** 1.251 (12.98) ***

0.010 (0.774) 0.002 (0.103)

1.331 (6.83) *** 1.058 (5.75) ***

-0.023 (-1.58) -0.006 (-0.04) -0.007 (-0.51)

1.342 (6.11) *** 1.975 (8.949) *** 1.489 (7.267) ***

F

0.704

135.1

0.148

11.13

0.427

44.26

0.378

36.24

0.652

109.7

0.306

26.68

0.655

111.3

0.742

168.3

0.674

119.2

0.495

57.85

0.526

65.5

0.741

168.3

0.44

48.99

0.356

33.12

0.385

37.3

0.576

80.08

0.471

52.81

Machinery Frigoglass Kleeman Furniture Dromeas Sato Varagis

t-statistic in parenthesis (***) indicate statistically significant factors at 1% level. Table 3. Regression Results on Beta: Ri − r f = Market Proxy ASE index (GI) (t) indicates the t-statistic.

γο 0.00053

t(γο) 0.157

γ o t + γ 1t β i + μ it γ1 0.00278

t(γ1)

Αdj. R2

0.997

0.0032

71

Messis, Iatridis, and Blanas, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 60-75

Table 4. Use of OLS to Eestimate the Higher Mmoment CAPM Bbased on Eq. (3) Asset ao Banks Alpha Agrotiki Aspis Attiki Egnatia Ellados Emporiki Ethniki Eurobank Geniki Kiprou Peireos

-0.010 (-1.19) -0.012 (-0.65) -0.001 (-0.089) -0.011 (-0.55) -0.012 (-1.03) -0.010 (-0.84) -0.020 (-2.24)** -0.013 (-1.42) -0.003 (-0.49) -0.03 (-2.01)** -0.003 (-0.34) 0.007 (0.65)

Machinery Frigoglass 0.021 (1.55) Kleeman -0.005 (-0.40)

ASE GI Beta 1

Skewness Beta 2

Kurtosis Beta 3

1.225 (6.69)*** 0.985 (2.58)*** 0.738 (2.65)*** 1.68 (3.92)*** 1.73 (7.07)*** 0.535 (1.909)** 1.518 (6.32)*** 1.304 (6.99)*** 1.01 (6.689)*** 1.05 (3.46)*** 1.05 (4.70)*** 1.19 (7.36)***

1.056 (0.89) 1.35 (0.53) -1.614 (-0.90) 3.44 (1.25) 1.29 (0.81) 3.86 (2.13)** 4.137 (2.68)*** 2.969 (2.47)*** 1.424 (1.464) 4.62 (2.32)** 0.32 (0.22) -0.95 (-0.92)

3.361 (0.34) -13.44 (-0.65) 24.41 (1.78)* -5.37 (-0.23) -10.85 (-0.816) 26.7 (1.764)* 8.34 (0.64) 15.56 (1.54) 0.197 (0.02) 30.49 (1.82)** 1.12 (0.09) 2.97 (0.34)

1.329 (4.10)*** 0.47 (1.72)*

-3.20 (-1.53) 2.577 (1.44)

-2.95 (-0.16) 40.2 (2.52)***

Adj. R2

F

0.699

44.5

0.137

4.08

0.463

17.7

0.381

12.92

0.654

37.6

0.346

11.2

0.685

43.2

0.76

62.5

0.68

41.09

0.529

22.7

0.539

23.6

0.75

58.86

0.471

18.35

0.392

13.48

Furniture Dromeas

-0.04 1.17 3.98 14.88 0.39 13.6 (-2.25) (3.21)*** (1.71)* (0.75) Sato -0.02 1.437 5.87 40.2 0.617 32.17 (-1.34) (4.09)*** (2.60)*** (2.12) Varagis -0.01 1.209 1.75 19.7 0.445 17.49 (-0.76) (3.69)*** (0.79) (1.06) t-statistic in parenthesis (*), (**), (***) indicate statistically significant factors at 10%, 5% and 1% level respectively. Table 5. Regression Results on Beta and Skewness: R it − R f = γ 0τ + γ 1t β i + γ 2 t SKW i + e it Market Proxy ASE index (GI)

γο 0.00038

t(γο)

γ1

t(γ1)

γ2

t(γ2)

Αdj. R2

0.109

0.0033

1.612

0.0007

1.687*

0.041

(t) indicates the t-statistic. (*) indicates statistically significant factors at 10% level.

72

Messis, Iatridis, and Blanas, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 60-75

Table 6. Regression Results on Beta and Kurtosis: R it − R f = γ 0τ + γ 1t β i + γ 3 t KUR i + e it Market Proxy ASE index (GI)

γο

t(γο)

γ1

t(γ1)

0.0015

0.36

0.0016

0.47

γ3 -0.007

t(γ3)

Αdj. R2

-0.79

0.0001

(t) indicates the t-statistic. Table 7. Regression Results on Beta, Skewness and Kurtosis:

R it − R

f

= γ

Market Proxy ASE index (GI)





0t + γ



1t

γο -0.0009

(t) indicates the t-statistic.

βi + γ t(γο)

2t

SKW

γ1

-0.11 0.0043



i



t(γ1) 0.59

3t

γ2



i

+ e it

t(γ2)

γ3

KUR

-0.0009 -0.67

t(γ3)

0.0003 0.23

Αdj. R2 0.029

73

Messis, Iatridis, and Blanas, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 60-75

74

Table 8. Use of OLS to Estimate Statistically Significant Coefficients of Higher Moment CAPM Based on Eq. (3) Asset ao Banks Alpha Agrotiki Aspis Attiki Egnatia Ellados Emporiki Ethniki Eurobank Geniki Kiprou Peireos

-0.010 (-0.84) -0.004 (-0.29) -0.008 (-0.70) 0.005 (0.28) -0.005 (-0.52) -0.010 (-0.84) -0.020 (-2.18)** -0.011 (-1.23) 0.002 (0.47) -0.03 (-2.01)** -0.002 (-0.26) 0.002 (0.37)

Machinery Frigoglass 0.021 (1.55) Kleeman 0.004 (0.4) Furniture Dromeas -0.023 (-1.58) Sato -0.02 (-1.34) Varagis -0.007 (-0.51)

ASE GI Beta 1 1.225 (11.79)*** 0.756 (3.33)*** 0.671 (2.512)*** 1.54 (6.02)*** 1.54 (10.47)*** 0.535 (1.909)** 1.642 (11.37)*** 1.534 (13.43)*** 0.99 (10.92)*** 1.05 (3.46)*** 1.06 (8.05)*** 1.251 (12.98)*** 1.285 (6.62)*** 0.578 (2.014)** 1.342 (6.11)*** 1.437 (4.09)*** 1.489 (7.267)***

Skewness Beta 2

Kurtosis Beta 3

30.3 (2.25)**

3.86 (2.13)** 3.70 (2.68)*** 2.16 (1.97)** 4.62 (2.32)**

26.7 (1.764)*

30.49 (1.82)*

-3.05 (-1.74)* 30.83 (2.12)**

5.87 (2.60)***

40.2 (2.12)**

Adj. R2

F

0.704

135.1

0.148

11.13

0.465

26.2

0.37

36.2

0.652

107.9

0.346

11.2

0.689

65.3

0.76

90.3

0.68

119.2

0.529

22.7

0.526

65.5

0.74

168.3

0.45

25.3

0.392

19.85

0.39

37.3

0.617

32.17

0.471

52.8

t-statistic in the parenthesis (*), (**), (***) indicate statistically significant factors at 10%, 5% and 1% level respectively.

Messis, Iatridis, and Blanas, International Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), March 2007, 60-75

Table 9. Comparison of the Models Using the Theil’s U2 Test Asset CAPM Banks Aspis 0.613 Ellados 0.675 Emporiki 0.302 Ethniki 0.263 Geniki 0.506 Machinery Frigoglass 0.555 Kleeman 0.633 Furniture Sato 0.421 The numbers in bold indicate better performance.

Higher moment CAPM 0.546 0.620 0.298 0.258 0.484 0.555 0.578 0.382

Table 10. Paired t-Test for theComparison between Higher Moment CAPM and CAPM Model Higher Moment CAPM

Mean 0.465

CAPM

0.496

T-Value

3.23**

(**) indicate statistically significant factors at 5% level.

P-Value

0.013

Difference

0.0308

75