Environment and economic growth: a convergence ...

3 downloads 0 Views 76KB Size Report
In early 1970s, the Club of Rome's Limits to Growth view (Meadows et al., 1972) ... environmental economists of the Club of Rome argued that the finiteness of.
Int. J. Global Environmental Issues, Vol. 9, Nos. 1/2, 2009

137

Environment and economic growth: a convergence approach Soumyananda Dinda Department of Economics and International Development, University of Bath, Bath, UK E-mail: [email protected] E-mail: [email protected] E-mail: [email protected] Abstract: The world economy faces a serious challenge from the global environmental degradation and appropriate environmental policy should be adopted in time to save it. The effective environmental policy prescription depends on the actual position of the economy: at what stage of growth/development the economy is. To be specific, we are interested to observe how economic growth is systematically linked to the position of the economy as well as that of the environment. Our model predicts that the average growth rate of output is inversely related to the initial level of output and directly related to the initial level of environmental condition. Keywords: economic growth; two-sector growth model; environmental capital; climate change; pollution; abatement; convergence; CO2 emission. Reference to this paper should be made as follows: Dinda, S. (2009) ‘Environment and economic growth: a convergence approach’, Int. J. Global Environmental Issues, Vol. 9, Nos. 1/2, pp.137–144. Biographical notes: Soumyananda Dinda is a Faculty at the Department of Economics and International Development, University of Bath, UK. Previously, he was Faculty at S.R. Fatepuria College, Beldanga, Murshidabad, under the University of Kalyani. He was a Guest Lecturer in the Department of Economics, Presidency College, Kolkata. He was also a Guest Lecturer in the Department of Economics, University of Calcutta. He was a Research Fellow at Economic Research Unit, Indian Statistical Institute since 1997. He has published papers on Ecological Economics; Economics and Human Biology; Journal of Socio-Economics; Indian Journal of Agricultural Economics.

1

Introduction

Concern about rising economic activity and environmental quality has focused attention on the relationship between economic growth and environmental degradation. The environmental effects due to economic growth have received increasing attention from economists, particularly; environment-versus-economic growth has evoked much 1 discussion in the last decade (i.e. 1990s). The relationship between economic growth and environment has been the objective of long debate in the economic literature for many years. This debate goes back to the controversy on the limits to growth at the Copyright © 2009 Inderscience Enterprises Ltd.

138

S. Dinda

beginning of the 1970s. Before 1970, there was a belief that the consumption of raw materials, energy and natural resources grow almost at the same rate (i.e. steady state). In early 1970s, the Club of Rome’s Limits to Growth view (Meadows et al., 1972) was forwarded about the concern for availability of natural resource of the Earth. The environmental economists of the Club of Rome argued that the finiteness of environmental resources would prevent economic growth from continuing forever and urged a zero-growth or steady state economy to avoid dramatic ecological scenarios in the future. The motivation for the mostly empirical studies in 1990s is only to find out the cause 2 of environmental problems and policy suggestions. The effective policy prescription depends on the actual position of the economy. By position we mean at what stage of growth the economy is. Our motivation for this study is to search for the evidence of the linking of economic growth and environment. To be specific, we are interested to observe how economic growth is systematically linked to the position of the economy as well as that of environment. This systematic link is a foundation for the convergence of an economy towards steady state (Barro and Sala-i-Martine, 1992). Convergence applies if a poor economy tends to grow faster than rich one, so that the poor country tends to catch up with the rich one in terms of the level of per capita income or product. This property corresponds to the concept of so-called β-convergence. In this context, convergence also occurs if the cross-sectional dispersion declines over time. We call this process σ-convergence. Convergence of first kind tends to generate convergence of the second kind. Thus, β-Convergence is a necessary but not a sufficient condition for σ-convergence. It should be noted that the poorer economies grow faster than rich ones if only difference across countries is initial levels of capital. All the economies move towards one common steady state level. This is known as absolute (or unconditional) β-convergence. Where there are structural differences across countries there will be conditional β-convergence: countries converge to different steady states but at a common speed. The conditional convergence is more realistic than absolute convergence in cross-country study. From the textbook literature (Barro and Sala -I- Martin, 1995), β-Convergence (assuming yit∗ remains constant between t − τ and t, the relationship) is

(

)

yit = e − βτ yit −τ + 1 − e − βτ yit∗

(1)

where yit is income per capita of ith country for time t and yit∗ is the steady state. Econometric model for β-Convergence is

(

)

yit = e − βτ yit −τ + 1 − e − βτ yit∗ + uit

(2)

where uit is the disturbance term with usual properties. In a cross-country study generally we assume that population growth rate (n), depreciation rate (δ) and discount rate (ρ) are nearly same for all countries, and we estimate the β-convergence model, in which all economies converge towards a common steady state level. In reality the population growth rate, depreciation rate and discount rate vary from country to country then we have to estimate the conditional β-convergence. So, the β-convergence is conditional by varying exogenous variables like 3 n, δ, ρ and also natural capital or environmental assets. In the β-convergence model all these variables are captured by yit∗ in Equation (2). Adding one by one these variables in Equation (2) we could estimate the conditional β (Mankiw et al., 1992).

Environment and economic growth

139

Now, suppose a natural capital or environmental asset is considered as an endogenous variable. So, we have to separate environmental asset from others at steady state also. In this context we follow Shioji (2001), who analyses public capital. Now we incorporate environment as a public capital in Equation (2). Steady state output per capita between t − τ and t depends positively on the value of the environmental capital at the beginning of the period (Eit−τ), assuming that environment per capita remains constant during the period. So, we postulate the following relationship: yit∗ = ψ Eit −τ + yi

(3)

where ψ > 0 measures the effect of environmental capital on steady state output per capita. All other factors affecting steady state output per capita are captured by the group/region-specific constant yi . Plugging the Equation (3) into Equation (2), we obtain

(

)

(

)

yit = e − βτ yit −τ + 1 − e − βτ ψ Eit −τ + 1 − e − βτ yi + uit

(4)

Thus, the growth of income has a direct link to the environment. Using two-sector endogenous growth model we may obtain similar relationship as Song (2000) finds. In the two-sector endogenous growth model (Dinda, 2005), two capitals are used – one is composite (physical and human) capital and other environmental (natural) capital that is public good by nature.4 In this paper, we study how income and natural (environmental) capital converge towards steady state. The natural question is whether the data support the predictions concerning the determinants of income growth. We want to investigate whether growth rate of income is high in a country having higher environmental stocks and low in a country having lower environmental assets. This is true, (under certain assumptions), low growth country has high level of emission (or pollution) but the high growth country has low emission level. For example, in the USA, annual average economic growth rate is low, approximately 2%, with higher level of emission5 (USA emits 23.58% of global emission in the World in 1997), while in India and China, economic growth rates are high with low (shared of global) emissions compared to the USA. Average economic growth rate of India is 5 to 6% and that of China is 8 to 10%. Emission levels in India and China are 4.3 and 5.6%, respectively, in 1997 (ORNL, 1998).

2

Empirical model

From Equation (4) we obtain the rate of convergence directly by estimating the following linear equation: ⎛ y ⎞ 1 log ⎜ it ⎟ = a − b1 log ( yit −τ ) + b2 log ( Eit −τ ) + uit T ⎝ yit −τ ⎠

where a = (1/ T )(1 − e − βτ ) yi , b1 = b2 = (1/ T )(1 − e − βτ )

(5)

140

S. Dinda

The simple empirical model for this study would be gi = a − b1 log y0i + b2 log E0i + ui

(6a)

gi = a − b1 log y0i + b2 log E0 i + b3 n + ui

(6b)

where g is the average growth rate of a country for the specified period, n is the population growth rate for the same period, y0 and E0 are income and environmental stock of the base year. Introducing the population growth rate in Equation (6(a)), we could find the conditional β-convergence in Equation (6(b)) in a simple way. Ideal conditional convergence could be Equation (6(b)) if we add other variables like the growth rate of infrastructure, education and health conditions etc. The significant b1 coefficient in Equation (6) is interpreted as evidence of β-convergence in the convention. The significant b2 coefficient in Equation (6) gives added flavour to the existing literature of β-convergence. For the quantitative analysis of Equation (6), we need the data on Y as well as on E. But in reality, we do not have any data on E. Truly, E is the stock variable and it is difficult to measure properly. Actually E is not well defined for individual country. Major sink of pollutants or emission is the ocean which do not belong to any nation. Next to the ocean, the forest is a major sink of carbon dioxide emission. Another important CO2 absorber is soil. So, land and forest both act as carbon sequestration and reduce CO2 from atmosphere and indirectly they help to check the global warming. 6 Therefore, the protected forest (green covered) area of a country could be a good proxy for E. The protected forest area absorbs CO2 in one hand and it also helps to stop the depletion of natural resources. Intuitively b2 should be positive, increasing protected forest area raises the base of economic activity.

3

Data

In this context we have used data on protected forest area as a proxy of environmental index. Per capita protected forest area may be a good proxy of environmental stock (Bimonte, 2002). The data on protected forest area (hector) is available only for 1970, 1980 and 1990. A few countries have data on it only in 1970 but more in 1980s. So, we consider the year 1980 as the base. These data are available in UNEP website GEO-3 compendium. For this present study, we have used cross-country panel data on per capita GDP (measured at 1985 International Price i.e. PPP) which are compiled by Summers and Heston (1994) (Mark 5.6).

4

Results

We choose per capita protected forest area of a country as a proxy of E. Few data on forest are available for individual nations. Poor people in under developed economies mainly rely on common forest resources. It should be mentioned that environmental protection necessitates closer attention to the qualitative characteristics of the process of development. The economic growth rate increases with rising per capita protected forest area of a nation (specifically less developed economy). This is because, the income of the

Environment and economic growth

141

people, who directly depend on forest, increases as protected forest area increases and the resource base of income will be widened (Dietza and Adger, 2003). In this situation, income base is protected for further income generation in future also. Thus, poverty eradication7 is possible through forest covered area protection in less developed countries. We calculate per capita protected area for each country for the given year. Here base year income, Y0 and base year environmental quality, E0 are actually Y80 and E80, respectively. Using these we estimate Equation (6) and results are presented in Tables 1 and 2. Statistically significant results are found only in the samples of Non-OECD and the World. The result of OECD countries is not significant. These findings suggest that as under developed countries increase their protected forest area, their economic growth rate may also improve. National policy of developing economies should be given high priority to protect and preserve their natural resources. Table 1 Variables Constant Log Y0 Log E0

R2 N

Results of unconditional convergence using protected forest area as environmental capital OECD 0.0098 (0.22) −0.013 (−0.44) 0.012 (0.35) 0.0304 21

Non-OECD

World

0.0086 (0.66)

−0.0112 (−1.28)

−0.032*** (−2.79) 0.029*** (2.71) 0.0892

−0.027*** (−2.68) 0.030*** (3.12) 0.1060

58

80

‘***’, ‘**’ and ‘*’ denote statistical significant at 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively. Note: Figures in parentheses are t-ratios. Table 2

Test results of conditional convergence adding population growth rate with protected forest area

Variables

OECD

Non-OECD

Constant Log Y0

0.004 (0.07)

0.038*** (2.66)

0.023** (2.03)

−0.011 (−0.37) 0.012 (0.35)

−0.033*** (−3.22) 0.025** (2.54)

−0.029*** (−3.19) 0.025*** (2.81)

−0.31 (−0.52) 0.0462

−1.09*** (−3.63) 0.2567

−1.05*** (−4.23) 0.2686

Log E0 n

R N

2

21

World

58

80

‘***’, ‘**’ and ‘*’ denote statistical significant at 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively. Note: Figures in parentheses are t-ratios.

These protected resources would be the basis for future economic growth and development. The protected forest covered area should have a maximum limit and beyond it growth rate may fall. Another point should be noted that the population growth rate has negative impact on economic growth rate particularly for less developed and developing countries (Non-OECD) and the World as a whole.

142

5

S. Dinda

Concluding remarks

This study finds the evidence of the linking of economic growth and environment and observes how economic growth is systematically linked to the economy and environment. The average growth rate of output is negatively related to the initial level of output and positively related to that of environment. We try to examine the model using some proxy of E data, viz.; per capita protected forest area. The empirical findings suggest that environmental stock directly affect the economic growth rate. In other word, if environmental stocks decline consequently economic growth rate falls or slows down. For policy prescriptions, this paper suggests that national policy of less developed countries should be towards protection and preservation of their own natural resources that would be the base for their activities and economic development. Each nation increases their protected forest area until an optimum level. Thus, the highest priority in their national policy should be given more emphasis on the land-use and land conversions. In this context, following Kyoto protocol, CO2 emission tradeable permit policy (Jensen and Rasmussen, 2000) could be implemented at international level to arrest global warming. Developed countries should provide some incentives to countries of under developed world having facility and/or ability to increase protected forest area. That means developed countries are ready to negotiate and compensate under developed countries and/or provide some benefits to Less Developed Countries (LDC) for not cutting trees or preserving forest that helps to reduce CO2 emission (national as well as global). Otherwise LDC may opt for alternative uses of land instead of protection of 8 forest. This preservation policy once implemented at international level, carbon absorption and/or sequestration increases and consequently atmospheric carbon dioxide concentration reduces. This whole system will be viable if and only if developed countries are ready to compensate less developed countries for protecting forest in terms of forgone development or alternative use of land. The non-availability of actual data on E is the major limitation of this study. In this paper, we use proxy variable instead of actual E. One can reexamine these results by using better proxy of E. Since E is not measurable accurately, we can develop an index of environmental quality that could be a better measurement of E. This is our future research agenda.

Acknowledgements I am grateful to the anonymous referees for their helpful comments. One part of this paper was presented at International Workshop on Climate change and Human security during 21–23 June 2005, at International Peace Research Institute, Oslo, Norway. Thanks to the participants for their valuable comments. Usual disclaimers, however, apply.

References Agras, J. and Chapman, D. (1999) ‘A dynamic approach to the environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis’, Ecological Economics, Vol. 28, No. 2, pp.267–277. Barro, R.J. and Sala -I- Martin, X. (1992) ‘Convergence’, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 100, pp.223–251.

Environment and economic growth

143

Barro, R.J. and Sala -I- Martin, X. (1995) Economic Growth, McGraw-Hill. Bimonte, S. (2002) ‘Information access, income distribution, and the environmental Kuznets curve’, Ecological Economics, Vol. 41, pp.145–156. Carson, R.T., Jeon, Y. and McCubbin, D.R. (1997) ‘The relationship between air pollution emissions and income: US data’, Environment and Developmental Economics, Vol. 2, pp.433–450. Cole, M.A., Rayner, A.J. and Bates, J.M. (1997) ‘The Environmental Kuznets Curve: an empirical analysis’, Environment and Development Economics, Vol. 2, pp.401–416. Coondoo, D. and Dinda, S. (2002) ‘Causality between income and emission: a country group-specific econometric analysis’, Ecological Economics, Vol. 40, pp.351–367. Dietza, S. and Adger, W.N. (2003) ‘Economic growth, biodiversity loss and conservation effort’, Journal of Environmental Management, Vol. 68, No. 1, pp.23–35. Dinda, S. (2004) ‘Environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis: a survey’, Ecological Economics, Vol. 49, No. 4, pp.431–455. Dinda, S. (2005) ‘A theoretical basis for the environmental Kuznets curve’, Ecological Economics, Vol. 53, No. 3, pp.403–413. Grossman, G.M. and Krueger, A.B. (1995) ‘Economic growth and the environment’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 110, No. 2, pp.353–377. Hayward, S. (2001) ‘Economic growth is key to environmental quality’, Viewpoint, 2 July. Holtz-Eakin, D. and Selden, T.M. (1995) ‘Stoking the fires?: CO2 emissions and economic growth’, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 57, pp.85–101. Jensen, J. and Rasmussen, T.N. (2000) ‘Allocation of CO2 emission permits: a general equilibrium analysis of policy instruments’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, Vol. 40, pp.111–136. Kahn, M.E. (1998) ‘A household level Environmental Kuznets curve’, Economics Letters, Vol. 59, pp.269–273. Koop, G. and Tole, L. (1999) ‘Is there an environmental Kuznets curve for deforestation?’ Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 58, pp.231–244. List, J.A. and Gallet, C.A. (1999) ‘The environmental Kuznets curve: does one size fit all?’ Ecological Economics, Vol. 31, pp.409–423. Mankiw, N.G., Romer, D. and Weil, D.N. (1992) ‘A contribution to the empirics of economic growth, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 107, pp.407–437. McConnell, K.E. (1997) ‘Income and the demand for environmental quality’, Environment and Development Economics, Vol. 2, pp.383–399. Meadows, D.H., Meadows, D.L., Randers, J. and Behrens, W. (1972) The Limits to Growth, New York: Universe Books. Moomaw, W.R. and Unruh, G.C. (1997) ‘Are environmental Kuznets curve misleading us? The case of CO2 emissions’, Environment and Development Economics, Vol. 2, pp.451–463. Oak Ridge National Laboratory, CDIAC, Environmental Science Division (1998) ‘Estimates of global, regional and national co2 emissions from fossil fuel burning, cement manufacturing and gas flaring: 1755–1996’, Available at: http://www.cdiac.esd.ornl.gov/epubs/ndp030/ global97.ems, updated on 2000.

Oak Ridge National Laboratory (1998) CDIAC, Environmental Science Division. Panayotou, T. (1999) ‘The economics of environments in transition’, Environment and Development Economics, Vol. 4, No. 4, pp.401–412. Sarkar, A.U. and McKillop, W. (1994) ‘Economic parameters for resource policy analysis in developing countries’, Journal of Environmental Management, Vol. 40, No. 4, pp.309–316. Selden, T. and Song, D. (1994) ‘Environmental quality and development: is there a Kuznets curve for air pollution emissions?’ Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, Vol. 27, pp.147–162.

144

S. Dinda

Shafik, N. (1994) ‘Economic development and environmental quality: an econometric analysis’, Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 46, pp.757–773. Shioji, E. (2001) ‘Public capital and economic growth: a convergence approach’, Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 6, pp.205–227. Song, E.Y. (2000) ‘The return to capital and convergence in a two sector model of endogenous growth’, International Economic Journal, Vol. 14, pp.143–163. Summers, R. and Heston, A. (1994) ‘A Penn World Table (version 5.6): an Expanded Set of International Comparisons: 1950–1992, NBER, PWT5.6’, Available at: http://www.nber.org/ pwt5.6. Suri, V. and Chapman, D. (1998) ‘Economic growth, trade and the environment: implications for the Environmental Kuznets Curve’, Ecological Economics, Vol. 25, pp.195–208. Torras, M. and Boyce, J.K. (1998) ‘Income, inequality and pollution: a reassessment of the Environmental Kuznets Curve’, Ecological Economics, Vol. 25, pp.147–160.

Notes 1

Grossman and Krueger (1995), Selden and Song (1994), Shafik (1994), Holtz-Eakin and Selden (1995), Cole et al. (1997), Carson et al. (1997), Kahn (1998), Koop and Tole (1999), List and Gallet (1999), Agras and Chapman (1999), McConnell (1997), Moomaw and Unruh (1997), Panayotou (1999), Suri and Chapman (1998), Torras and Boyce (1998), Bimonte (2002) and Dinda (2004, 2005). 2 Before adopting any policy, it is important to understand the nature and causal relationship between economic growth and environmental quality (Coondoo and Dinda, 2002). 3 Now consider the situation that climate change has impact on the steady state exogenously. We measure the impact of climate change (ε, say) on n, δ and ρ as (∂n / ∂ε ) ≺ 0 , (∂δ / ∂ε ) 0 and (∂ρ / ∂ε ) 0 , respectively. For example, as climate changes some new disease may be grown up and that may affect human growth n and thereby affect steady state growth rate. Similarly, discount rate for future consumption increases as climate continuously deteriorates/changes. 4 Generally, the social assets could be private property of the society because other society could not use that asset. We assume that central planner is the owner of the social assets, so, E can be treated as private property of the planner. 5 High environmental stock may exist. Recently one report points out that environmental stocks especially protected forest covered area has reached roughly 44% of the state of Michigan, in USA (see Hayward, 2001). Few developed countries like Russia, Canada, USA, Australia, etc. have both natural resource and physical capital. There is some exception that low level of (physical and human) capitals are associated with low natural (resources) capitals. 6 We can take national protected area of a country or the percentage of land under forest and woods as a proxy of environment. The data on percentage of land under forest for each country is available for the year 1970, 1975, 1980, 1985 and 1990. 7 Poor people rely more on common forest resources. These common resources decrease as economy develops. So, income or livelihood of mass people decline and gradually fall into the poverty trap. So, protection of common resources is actually protecting the income of mass people. So, common resource protection should be one policy to eradicate poverty (Sarkar and McKillop, 1994). 8 Especially reference to the rain forest or tropical forest, which mostly belong to under developed countries.