Governance of Vocational Education and Training (VET)

5 downloads 5322 Views 232KB Size Report
school or other kind of technical institution (e.g. kind of industrial sector, guilds or ..... companies use the protected status of the apprentices to use them as cheap ...
Governance  of  Vocational  Education  and  Training  (VET)     Dr.  Ludger  Deitmer,  University  of  Bremen,  Institute  Technology  and  Education,   deitmer@uni-­‐bremen.de     1. Abstract     2. Introduction   3. Three  VET  Governance  Models   4. Analysis  of  VET  governance  models  within  wider  context   5. Strength  &  Weaknesses  of  apprentice  VET   6. The  governance  evaluation  tool:  guiding  principles,  evaluation  criteria  and   evaluation  process   7. Exemplary  results  from  previous  governance  workshops   8. Outlook   on   the   current   problems   within   Indian   Apprenticeship   and   the   need   for   Governance   9. Conclusions   10. References     1.  Abstract   The   article   discusses   the   importance   of   governance   models   for   the   steering   and   coordination   of   different   vocational   education   and   training   systems.   Three   kind   of   ideal   typed   VET   systems   (state,   market   and   mixed)   are   analysed   by   six   aspects   in   order   to   characterize  particular  strength’s  and  weaknesses.  There  is  a  set  of  evaluation  criteria  for   this   governance   approach   designed   and   reflected   in   stakeholder   evaluation   workshops.   Finally   the   further   development   of   the   Indian   apprenticeship   system   is   discussed.   In   the   conclusion   I   will   summarize   some   key   statements   based   on   the   INAP   commission   suggestion  towards  the  architecture  of  an  Innovative  Apprenticeship.       2.  Introduction     There   is   a   renewed   interest   into   dual   structured   vocational   education   and   training   to   be   noted   (cf.  Rauner,   Smith   2010;   INAP  2012;   Deitmer   et   al.   2013).   Prominent   recent  example   as   the   one   in   Malaysia   in   implementing   a   new   dual   training   system,   NDTS   (Rashidi   2014)   give  rise  to  further  discussions.  Several  other  countries  are  newly  adopting  –  or  aiming  to   do  so  –  apprenticeship  approaches  that  build  on  the  ‘dual  principles’:  as  a  combination  of   workplace  learning  in  an  enterprise  with  corresponding  classroom  teaching  in  an  vocational   school   or   other   kind   of   technical   institution   (e.g.   kind   of   industrial   sector,   guilds   or   chambers  based  training  centre).     But   to   transfer   VET   system   or   even   elements   of   it   into   other   industrial   cultures   is   a   very   complex   and   difficult   task   because   this   touches   industrial   conditions,   traditions   and   attitudes,  which  will  not  change  quickly.  This  touches  therefore  not  only  economic  but  also   social   and   issues.   Like   for   example   the   different   motives   of   stakeholders;   e.g.   company   owners  and  managers,  official  and  unofficial  trainers,  vocational  teachers,  pubic  authority   officials  and  sometimes  also  the  social  partners  such  as  employee  association  and  workers   unions.     It   is   worth   to   discuss   the   question   of   the   evaluation   of   Governance   structures   of   VET;   because  without  an  sustainable  Governance  strategy  the  implementation  of  new  training   arrangement   may   fail   while   some   stakeholders   are   not   convinced   or   many   other   factors    

1  

take   considerable   influence   (e.g.   bad   image   of   the   vocational   occupation;   missing   technical   learning   infrastructure,   missing   training   material,   missing   knowledge   and   skills   at   trainer   and/or  teachers,  unattractive  allowances).     A   governance   strategy   could   be   called   sustainable   if   different   stakeholder   are   willing   to   perform   in   a   complementary   way   and   are   willing   to   support   each   other.   Own   action   is   coordinated   with   the   action   of   others.   In   other   words   the   companies   are   competitors   on   the  market  for  goods  and  services  but  cooperate  for  example  on  the  personal  development   level.   Contradictory   expectations   of   e.g.   company   trainers,   vocational   teachers   could   hinder   the   development   of   a   collective   understanding   of   vocational   learning   processes.   How  can  these  differences  be  better  integrated?     If  to  perform  a  more  integrative  governance  strategy  it  needs  to  find  out  what  could  be  the   key   criteria   for   this:   Where   is   consent   or   dissent   on   these   governance   criteria?.   If   such   a   collective  or  more  balanced  strategy  is  formed  it  should  allow  better  decisions  and  help  to   form  an  integrative  training  agenda;  issues  for  changing  insufficient  practise’s  and  heading   towards  better  training  practise.  The  following  presented  approach  might  be  understood  as   a  evaluation  tools  to  find  out  the  obstacles  and  hindrances  in  order  to  overcome  these  as   early  as  possible  to  develop  and  collective  strategy  under  key  stakeholders.       3.  Three  VET  Governance  Models   In   vocational   education   and   training   three   ideal   types   of   regulation   and   governance   are   usually   distinguished   on   the   dominant   either   from   the   state,   the   market   or   professional   groups  initiatives.  The  prevalent  typology  in  policy  research  distinguishes  three  models  of   governance,   which   can   be   termed   market-­‐driven,   state-­‐controlled   and   occupation-­‐driven   or   corporatist   VET   governance   (see   Greinert   1998,   19–22;   Clematide   et   al.   2005,   3–4).   In   the  following  the  three  models  are  explained  in  terms  of  their  regulative  momentum  and   their  rational  of  agency  (Rauner  et.al.  2010).   The   market-­‐driven  model  of  VET  governance   is   characterised   by   the   immediate   control   of   vocational   qualification   by   the   employment   system   and   the   demand   on   the   labour   market.   Vocational  qualification  is  oriented  towards  the  requirements  of  employers  and  takes  place   on   the   job   and   in   a   private   sector   of   training   providers   offering   job-­‐related   learning   modules.   The   responsibility   for   the   training   process   rests   with   the   learners,   who   are   expected   to   acquire   the   qualifications   required   by   employers   on   their   own.   Typical   examples  of  this  model  are  the  United  States  and  Japan,  where  the  relative  absence  of  a   regulated   VET   system   is   associated   with   a   large   number   of   students   attending   upper   secondary  schools  and  higher  education.  In  this  system  the  access  to  VET  is  controlled  by   employers  as  “customers”,  whose  needs  and  demands  determine  the  contents  of  training   so  that  the  transfer  of  qualifications  from  one  company  to  another  is  difficult  (cf.  Greinert   1998,  20–21).  On  the  one  hand  this  system  is  regarded  as  quite  flexible  and  adapted  to  the   needs  of  the  employment  system,  on  the  other  hand  the  dependence  on  the  private  supply   of  training  opportunities  and  the  risk  of  underinvestment  in  vocational  education  are  seen   as  serious  flaws  of  this  model  (cf.  Clematide  et  al.  2005,  3).   The   state-­‐controlled   model   of   VET   is   characterised   by   a   dominance   of   school-­‐based   vocational  education,  which  is  subject  to  a  relatively  tight  regulation  by  state  authorities.  In   this  model,  which  is  prevalent,  for  instance,  in  France  or  China,  the  regulation  is  based  on   the  school’s  logic  of  action  and  includes  a  focus  on  civic  education.  Enterprises  do  not  have   an   institutionalised   role   in   this   system,   but   serve   as   suppliers   of   internships   while   all   regulatory  functions  –  planning,  management  and  control  –  are  concentrated  in  the  public    

2  

sector.   The   contents   of   vocational   education   are   typically   based   on   theoretical   and   academic   types   of   education   (cf.   Greinert   1998,   21–22).   Due   to   the   integration   into   the   state-­‐controlled   education   system   there   is   a   relatively   close   connection   to   general   education.  Moreover,  the  supply  of  training  opportunities  is  independent  of  the  provision   of   training   places   by   private   companies.   The   major   difficulty   of   this   system   is   the   weak   linkage  to  the  labour  market  (cf.  Clematide  et  al.  2005,  3).     Type  of  Governance  model   rational  of  agency   Employers   a s   c ustomers;  individual  training   Market  driven   company  needs  determine  VE  curriculum  &   company  training,  transfer  of  skills  to  other   companies  rather  difficult  because  many   different  certificates;  VET  example  countries  :   UK,  US,  Ireland  and  Japan   Merely  school  based,  schools  logic  of  action,   State  driven   more  theory  driven,  less  work  process  driven;   little  real  work  orders,  rather  costly  model  while   training  labs  need  constant  modernisation;   more  simulated  instead  of  real  work  task   completion,  example  VET  countries:  France,   China,  Spain,  Portugal,  Poland   Occupation  driven  and  /  or  cooperatist  VET   Mixed  system  regulation;  employers   associations  great  influence,  in  some  countries   governance   also  the  unions,  based  collective  bargening  for   defining  occupations  and  their  constant   modernisation;  Variations  of  systems  in   countries  like  Germany,  Austria,  Danmark,   Netherlands,  Northern  regions  of  Italy  and   Switzerland  

  Diagramme  1.:  Three  main  VET  systems  and  their  rationality     The   third   model   is   referred   to   as   occupation-­‐based   or   corporatist   regulation   (cf.   Greinert   1998,   19–20).   This   model   is   derived   from   the   apprenticeship   tradition   in   the   craft   trades.   It   is  characterised  by  a  strong  influence  of  the  training  companies  and  the  chambers  and  or   professional   associations,   the   corporate   bodies   that   represent   the   business   and   trade   community.   This   concerns   the   entry   conditions   to   training   as   well   as   the   definition   of   training   contents   and   the   ways   the   training   and   teaching   processes   are   examined.   Today   occupation-­‐based  regulation  is  part  of  “mixed”  systems  of  cooperative  governance  in  which   the   regulation   of   vocational   education   takes   place   in   a   plural   network   of   state   bodies,   enterprises   or   employers’   associations   as   well   as   trade   unions   or   professional   associations.   Variations   of   these   mixed   models   of   regulations   can   be   found   in   systems   of   cooperative   (dual   or   alternating)   VET   as   they   exist   in   Austria,   Denmark,   Germany   Norway   and   Switzerland.       4.  Analysis  of  VET  governance  models  within  wider  context   A   major   finding   of   institutional   studies   on   advanced   industrial   economies   is   that   the   ability   of  a  country  to  develop  human  capital  is  conditioned  by,  and  reflected  in,  the  institutional   context   of   political   economy   and   adjacent   domains   (industrial   relations,   partisan   politics,    

3  

etc.).  The  analysis  of  VET  governance  models  needs  to  consider  the  wider  national  context   (Rauner  et.al.  2010)   It   has   been   argued   that   a   coordinated   VET   governance   model   records   advantages   compared  with  a  market-­‐  or  state-­‐oriented  governance  model.  Instead  of  delegation  to  the   State   or   the   Market,   coordination   ensures   the   optimal   mix   of   individual   autonomy   and   collective   obligations.   It   combines   a   statutory   core   (regulation   of   training   standards   including   examination)   with   flexible   elements   (firm-­‐level   flexible   implementation).   This   is   the   outcome   of   historical   power   struggles   between   different   interests   (Busemeyer   2013)   and  it  can  be  found  in  some  features  of  the  political  economy  of  collective  skill  formation:   for  instance,  training  content  regulation,  which  is  defined  statutorily  but  firms  can  decide   how  many  apprentices  to  hire  and  for  which  occupations  to  train  them.     Moreover,  compulsory  membership  in  Chambers  is  balanced  by  voluntary  membership  in   employers’   associations.   Likewise,   unions   and   vocational   schools   are   involved   in   local   governance,   but   employers   have   the   upper   hand.   Finally,   individual   firms   decide   training   investments,  but  collective  agreements  define  apprentice  pay  levels  and  over  social  taxes   and   health   insurances.   A   number   of   advantages   seem   indeed   to   be   associated   with   coordinated   governance   model:   smooth   transitions   from   school   to   employment,   comparative  strong  intermediate-­‐level  skills  and  politically  sustainable  solutions  based  on   consensus.   On   the   other   hand,   this   would   still   have   some   disadvantages   such   as   long   decision-­‐making   and   inflexible   processes,   the   potential   influence   of   special   interests,   weakness   with   regard   to   structural   reforms.   The   coordinated   model   (typical   for   apprenticeships)  an  almost  exclusively  be  identified  in  countries  classified  as  ‘collective  skill   formation   systems’   where   occupational   space   dominates.   These   can   be   found   in   work-­‐ based  VET  systems  such  as  Austria,  Switzerland,  Denmark,  Germany,  the  Netherlands.     Conversely,   a   market-­‐centred  VET  governance  system   might   constitute   an   obstacle   rather   than   an   asset   for   high   quality   skill   formation,   since   it   could   be   a   response   of   demand   to   rising  relative  unit  cost,  due  to  government  budgetary  policy.  If  the  government  chooses  to   reduce  the  real  growth  of  public  spending  on  the  service,  its  output  grows  more  slowly  and   it  may  even  fall.  The  effect  on  output  may  involve  quantity,  quality,  or  both.  If  the  public   buyer  gives  priority  to  quantity,  then  quality  suffers.  VET  governance  in  liberal  democracies   encourage   the   prioritisation   of   quantity   over   quality,   as   a   result   of   a   number   of   factors,   namely:   restricted   public   spending,   intertwined   with   the   electoral   politics   of   public   spending   and   taxation;   the   greater   visibility   of   policies   prioritising   quantity   and   the   consequent   political   reward;   the   need   of   balancing   social   justice   and   efficiency   among   public   goals;   the   marketisation   and   rebranding   techniques,   to   highly   publicise   policy   innovations.   ‘Apprenticeship’s   contribution   to   intermediate   skills   will   continue   to   falter   until   better   ways   of   ensuring   quality   and   eliciting   employer   commitment   are   developed.   Continental  apprenticeship  suggests  promising  alternatives’  (Ryan,  Unwin,  2001,  112).       5.  Strenght  and  Weaknesses  of  the  apprenticeship  model   The   situation   is   somewhat   different   in   dual   apprenticeship   training.   This   model   is   characterised  by  the  fact  that  the  vocational  education  and  training  system  is  composed  of   two   independent   but   interrelated   subsystems,   namely,   an   in-­‐company   training   sector   organised   by   private   enterprises   and   a   corresponding   sector   of   vocational   school   instruction   for   which   the   state   or   associations   or   professional   bodies   are   responsible   (cf.   Greinert   1998,   23–24).   Although   this   model   appears   at   a   first   glance   as   a   combination   of   market  and  state  regulation,  there  are  also  considerable  elements  of  occupation-­‐based  and    

4  

corporatist   governance.   In   Germany,   for   instance,   the   traditional   strong   role   of   the   occupational  principle  (Berufsprinzip)  entails  a  control  of  the  access  to  vocational  training   by   the   occupational   groups   concerned.   Following   the   tradition   of   the   guilds   and   other   professional   association,   they   participate   in   the   formulation   of   training   curricula   frameworks   and   influence   the   organisation   of   the   external   vocational   examinations   in   practical   and   technical   terms   through   the   chambers   of   commerce   and   industry   and   craft   trade,   which   are   the   bodies   that   officially   represent   the   companies   from   the   different   sectors  and  branches   In   the   following   some   strength   and   weaknesses   of   the   dual   system   model   system   are   summarised   and   this   due   to   the   fact   that   cooperate   governance   of   the   dual   system   is   covering  quite  a  lot  of  stakeholders  and  requires  regulation  (Arnold,  Gonon  2006,  101).       Strength   Weaknesses   Under  economic  recession  the  training   1.   School  to  work  transition  ratio;  youth   2.  

3.  

4.   5.  

unemployment;  direct  involvement  and   investment  of  the  economic  forces   Learning  by  practise  and  action,  learning   within  real  and  holistic  business  task:   planning,  production,  self  –  control    and  QM   integrated  (QDCA  cycle)   Good  cost-­‐benefit  ratio:  cost  of  training  are   shared  under  state  and  economy;  public    or   semi  like  body  covers  only  VET  school;  private   companies  invest  into  VET  training   Principle  of  subsidiarity;  collective  values  and   befits  are  shared  despite  individual  company   interest   Both  individual  (apprentice)  and  collective   (company)  benefits:  forms  professional   identity  and  vocational  commitment  

6.   Early  recognition  of  technical  needs  and  

market  change  because  of  company  force   involvement  and  there  associations  

offers  can  be  reduced;  offer  on  training   places  can  be  difficult;   It  can  be  the  case  that  the  individual  in   company  training  system  is  weak;  there  is   too  little  control  over  the  quality  of   apprenticeship   Apprenticeship  is  misused  as  cheap  labour:   not  doing  the  right  value  work  task    

Learning  venues  coordination  weak;   resources  for  trainer  and  teacher  and   learning  environment  are  missing   Critical  mass  of  stakeholders  needed  to   follow  such  approach;  if  not  survival  of  the   VET  system  is  under  question;  difficult  to   govern  and  time  consuming  to  build   consensus   Keeping  occupation‘s  up  to  date  as  an   extra  effort;  requires  an  constant   innovation  dialogue  under  stakeholders;   needs  cluster  strategy  support  

  One  of  the  strongest  arguments  of  the  strength  of  the  dual  model  is  producing  very  little   youth  employment.  Compared  to  other  European  states  those  countries  with  a  dual  model   have   the   lowest   youth   unemployment   ratio.   The   company   is   not   only   providing   work   place   but   also   a   learning   venue.   This   has   positive   effects   on   the   school   to   work   ratio.   This   means   that   apprentices   are   real   employees   under   special   status   (allowances,   lower   social   taxes   etc.)   within   the   training   company.   A   high   percentage   of   them   are   needed   as   future   employees  and  stay  on  after  their  training  time.     The  critical  point  is  the  provision  of  enough  training  places  in  companies.  This  is  the  case   when   national   or   global   markets   come   into   economic   recession   (e.g.   see   the   Japanese   difficulties  on  transition  of  young  people  into  their  labour  market).     Another  stronghold  for  dual  training  is  that  it  follows  the  concept  of  work  process  learning.   The   real   character   of   the   work   tasks   –   and   its   limitation   to   simulate   them   in   schools   or   other  bodies  -­‐  offers  the  chance  for  learning  to  deal  with  inside  and  outside  the  company    

5  

customers.   The   VET   students   learn   better   to   plan,   do,   act   and   own   control   of   work   task   (QDCA   cycle)   (Deitmer   2011b).   This   esteems   them   for   self-­‐control   and   in   such   a   way   that   it   is   also   productive   for   the   company.   This   make’s   it   easier   for   the   company   to   realise   productivity   increase;   which   work   even   when   technical   change   takes   place.   To   establish   such  work  and  learning  system  requires  the  existence  of  a  company  internal  apprenticeship   management   system   (e.g.   designated   apprenticeship   training   plan,   co-­‐trainers,   training   methods  etc.).  It  is  the  point  that  such  in  company  trainers  are  in  place  (they  should  have   the   expertise   to   implement   and   control   in-­‐company   training   plans)   which   are   capable   of   establishing   an   company   internal   structures   (e.g.   training   plans,   identifying   key   work   and   learning   task,   following   the   training   framework   of   the   occupation,   individual   apprentice   working   place   rotation   plan:   road   maps).   The   weakness   is,   that   there   is   no   real   quality   control   of   the   individual   in-­‐company   training.   It   can   be   the   case   that   the   individual   in   company  training  system  is  too  weak:    too  little  challenging  work  task,  apprentices  do  by   over   50%   such   task   where   they   only   can   learn   very   little   (doing   side   work   which   do   not   require  the  skilled  worker;  only  simple  work;  no  rewarding  complex  and  challenging  work   task,  no  touch  to  customer)  (Deitmer  2011a,  Rauner,  Wittig  2013).   While  at  least  over  50  %  of  the  cost  of  the  dual  system  is  financed  by  private  sources  makes   this   system   relatively   attractive   for   public   bodies;   here   the   public   treasurer.   While   the   companies   also   have   to   invest   into   the   training   there   is   all   the   time   the   danger   that   companies   use   the   protected   status   of   the   apprentices   to   use   them   as   cheap   labour   and   have  them  work  on  task  with  little  learning  potential.     In   dual   VET   countries   like   Germany   or   Switzerland   there   are   no   direct   control   systems   in   place.   This   while   too   many   efforts   are   needed;   because   these   countries   have   training   of   trainers  etc.  which  helps  to  overcome  this  weakness.  In  Cost  benefit  studies  (Rauner,  Wittig   2013)  it  can  be  shown  that  the  productivity  of  apprentices  in  an  company  is  above  average   when  two  main  quality  features  are  given:  the  strong  emphasis  on  self-­‐organised  learning   and  the  incorporation  of  learning  and  learners  into  the  production  process  to  allow  them   to  make  work  experiences.  The  principle  of  subsidiarity  is  followed  when  the  stakeholders   of   the   VET   systems   take   more   strongly   their   position,   this   is   the   case,   when   the   societal   forces  keep  on  going  to  undertake  engagement  into  training  duties  of  people  and  the  state   can   take   over   rather   are   subsidarian   role.   The   state   finances   only   the   school   part   of   dual   VET.   Individual   and   collective   benefits   can   be   gained   when   companies   –   who   are   normally   competitors  –  are  organising  collective  benefits  in  regard  to  training  when  they  share  the   knowledge   about   good   training   performance.   This   means   that   overall   work   force   is   relatively  high  skilled  and  which  makes  them  just  less  vunerable  against  turbulences  on  the   labour   market   changes.   That   there   is   early   recognition   on   technical   changes   and   its   integration  into  training  programmes  is  a  further  plus.     Keeping   the   occupation‘s   up   to   date   is   an   extra   challenge   for   companies   and   their   representing   associations   or   chambers;   which   requires   an   constant   Innovation   dialogue   under  stakeholders.     The   discussion   of   the   strength   and   weaknesses   shows   that   the   model   require   relevant   regulation   and   multiple   governance.   Such   an   multi   measure   and   multi   actor   system   is   represented   by   many   stakeholders   from   different   interest   groups   which   could   harmonise   and   work   together   towards   an   common   goal.   But   still   they   have   the   freedom   to   keep   outside   of   such   a   collective   arrangement.   Therefore   the   innovation   dialogue   under   the   stakeholders   is   needed;   which   requires   moderation   and   coordination.   A   sustainable   and   effective   VET   governance   model   should   therefore   include   a   high   degree   of   coordination    

6  

between   the   bodies   involved   and   should   combine   elements   of   input   orientation   like   participation   and   deliberation   with   elements   of   output   orientation   such   as   performance   orientation,  efficiency  and  quality  assurance  (Rauner,  Wittig  2013).       6.  The  governance  evaluation  tool:  guiding  principles,  evaluation  criteria  and  evaluation   process   The  evaluation  tool  developed  at  the  Institute  Technology  and  Education  (ITB),  University   of   Bremen   provides   support   for   the   assessment   of   governance   mechanisms   in   VET   by   means   of   expert   or   stakeholder   workshops   (Deitmer   2011a,   Rauner,   Wittig   2013).   Two   objectives  can  be  achieved  with  this  tool,  namely     • a   monitoring   of   the   current   state   of   affairs   with   regard   to   the   governance   and   management  of  selected  VET  systems  and     • an   in-­‐depth   evaluation   of   selected   factors   and   dimensions   of   VET   governance   systems  by  national  experts.   The   focus   of   the   methodology   is   on   national   and   or   regional   experts   who   are   concerned   with  management  and  governance  issues  of  their  VET  systems.  The  experts  participate  in  a   workshop   where   they   express   their   views   on   the   current   state   of   affairs   and   rate   the   governance   activities   by   means   of   the   questionnaire   described   above.   The   role   of   the   moderator   is   to   support   the   evaluation   process   and   to   make   sure   that   all   participants   have   the   opportunity   to   explain   their   views.   Both   the   diverging   and   the   converging   ratings   on   the   various   criteria   are   clarified   and   discussed.   The   final   discussion,   in   which   the   participants  look  for  a  consensus,  offers  the  opportunity  for  a  deeper  understanding  of  the   issues  for  all  participants.   This  model  is  operationalised  by  an  evaluation  tool  with  deserves  of  several  categories  and   criteria   that   are   listed   and   explained   below.   There   are   seven   main   criteria,   of   which   five   relate  to  the  integration  of  the  system  (i.e.  coordination  and  fragmentation)  and  two  to  the   dimension  of  input  and  output  orientation.  These  main  criteria  are  the  following:     Category  A:  Integrative  systems  from  coordination  to  fragmentation   Criteria  1:  Consistency  of  the  legal  framework.     Full   Consistency   is   given   when   an   unified   legal   framework   exists   even   when   it   covers   different   legal   domains.   For   a   dual   VET   this   would   mean   that   different   laws,   e.g.   from   educational,   labour   market   and   economical   domains   would   supplement   each   other.   This   is   the   case   when   one   level   of   government   (national,   regional,   or   local   level)   is   responsible   for   the  enactment  of  the  rules  governing  VET.  Under  this  criteria  it  has  to  be  also  assessed  how   strictly   a   legal   binding   cooperation   of   the   learning   venues   is   demanded.   If   all   learning   venues   of   vocational   education   are   covered   by   one   relevant   law   the   conditions   for   binding   regulation  is  fulfilled.  In  this  case  the  quality  of  these  regulations  has  to  be  assessed.  If  in-­‐ company   training   and   school   instruction   fall   into   different   legal   domains   it   has   to   be   assessed  how  effectively  the  cooperation  between  the  learning  venues  is  supported  by  the   relevant  laws.       Criteria  2:  Cooperation  of  the  various  bodies.     It   is   assessed   here   whether   the   VET   laws   reflect   roles   and   interest   of   all   partners   and   learning  venue  bodies  involved.  This  includes  the  sub  criterium  how  the  good  cooperation   is   achieved.   This   includes   the   existence   of   an   intense   VET   dialogue   under   social   partners,   colleges  and/or  researchers.  The  quality  of  participation  in  the  VET  dialogue  (cooperation    

7  

of  all  relevant  bodies  in  the  organisation  and  shaping  of  vocational  education)  depends  on   whether   there   is   a   moderating   and   coordinating   institution   that   has   the   competence   to   fulfil  this  function  adequately  for  the  entire  system.     Criteria  3:  Innovation  strategies.     Innovative   strategies   covers   all   such   criteria   which   help   to   develop   and   evaluate   new   strategies   for   the   improvement   of   the   VET   governance   performance.   For   the   quality   of   cooperation  of  the  learning  venues  there  is  the  chance  to  improve  them  by  pilot  projects   and   programmes.   These   programmes   aim   to   exploit   the   potentials   of   both   learning   venues   and   to   connect   them   to   each   other.   Following   PISA   and   other   VET   related   competence   assessments  there  is  widespread  attention  to  instruments  and  methods  that  allow  for  the   evaluation  of  vocational  education  and  training  effects  in  terms  of  the  learning  processes  of   VET  students.  The  quality  of  the  relevant  innovation  strategies  has  to  be  assessed.       Criteria  5:  Allocation  of  strategic  and  operational  functions.   Often   VET   is   allocated   to   one   policy   area,   like   education   or   labour   market   policy,   which   often  leads  to  the  neglect  of  other  policy  fields.  To  achieve  a  balance  already  in  the  legal   framework  it  has  to  be  assessed  to  what  extent  this  strategy  was  successful.  The  plurality   of  overarching  policy  objectives  of  vocational  education  is  reflected  in  the  involvement  of   various  bodies.  It  has  to  be  assessed  whether  the  agents  within  the  VET  system  represent  a   good   equilibrium   of   the   policy   areas.   Occupational   profiles,   curricula   and   training   plans   are   an   expression   of   empirically   established   qualification   requirements   as   well   as   normative   rules   derived   from   the   educational   objectives.   Furthermore,   a   compromise   needs   to   be   found   between   the   company’s   interest   in   specialised   qualifications   that   “fit   in”   exactly,   the   interest  of  the  sector  in  rather  broad  profiles  and  the  individuals’  interest  in  a  career.  These   interests   and   the   underlying   political   orientations   influence   curriculum   development   procedures.  It  has  to  be  assessed  how  successfully  an  equilibrium  is  achieved.       Category  B:  Input  versus  output  orientation     Criteria  6:  Outcome  orientation   The   legal   framework   includes   mandatory   objectives   and   benchmarks   (standards)   for   vocational   education   and   training.   This   item   aims   to   assess   how   strictly   educational     standards  in   the   sense   of  competences   to  be   acquired   by   the   learners   are   fixed   in   the   legal   VET  framework.  The  achievement  made  in  VET  is  evaluated  systematically.  This  means  that   it   has   to   be   assessed   whether   there   exists,   at   the   level   of   the   national   VET   system,   a   practice   of   evaluating   the   attainment   of   quantitative   benchmarks   like   entry   rates,   youth   unemployment,   external   exam   completion   rates   or   items   concerning   the   transition   rate   into  the  employment  system  or  to  higher  education.       Criteria  7:  Input  orientation   The   legal   framework   is   based   on   the   principle   of   closed   curricula.   The   term   “closed   curricula”   refers   to   regulations   that   specify   not   only   the   fundamental   objectives   of   a   training  programme,  but  also  the  details  of  its  realization  (down  to  the  concrete  lesson!).   This   would   mean   that   there   is   little   room   left   for   local   adaptations   and   challenging   the   teachers  competence.  It  has  to  be  assessed  to  what  extent  the  legal  framework  leaves  the   teachers   and   trainers  good   opportunities  to   shape   the  training  process   locally  and   within   each  training  location.  The  completion  of  a  specific  curriculum  is  an  admission  requirement    

8  

for  vocational  examinations.  It  has  to  be  assessed  how  strictly  the  completion  of  a  specific   learning  trajectory  in  the  sense  of  a  regulated  training  programme  with  a  fixed  content  and   duration  or  in  the  sense  of  a  fixed  period  of  professional  work  experience  (in  the  case  of   advanced   programmes)   is   set   as   a   mandatory   requirement   for   the   admission   to   the   final   examination.       The   above   described   seven   main   criteria   are   broken   down   into   30   sub-­‐criteria   and   brought   together   into   a   questionnaire.   The   questionnaire   is   the   basis   for   the   evaluation   and   discussion   process   amongst   experts   from   different   expertise   areas;   like   for   example   VET   experts  from  associations,  schools,  companies,  unions  and  ministries.  The  expert  take  part   in  the  VET  governance  assessment  workshop  under  moderation  of  an  external  evaluation   team.   The   experts   are   asked   to   judge   and   rate   the   sub   criteria   on   a   scale   from   1   (=   not   realised)  to  10  (=  fully  realised).  The  external  evaluation  team  collates  the  individual  ratings   on  a  wall  chart  or  by  computer  system  for  everyone  to  see  and  moderates  the  discussion.   On  the  basis  of  the  often  different  individual  ratings,  the  team  moderates  a  discussion  with   the   aim   to   explain   first   of   all   the   rational   for   the   ratings   by   the   individual   experts   and   secondly  to  achieve  a  consensus  in  order  to  formulate  an  collective  expert  opinion  of  the   different   criteria.   This   includes   also   the   documentation   of   dissent;   which   is   still   possible   that   the   positions   cannot   reach   each   other   and   stay   different   even   in   the   light   of   the   discussion.     The   aggregated   answers   determine   the   position   of   the   VET   system.   The   position   on   the   horizontal   axis   “integration   of   the   system”   is   defined   by   the   mean   of   the   values   for   the   main   criteria   1   to   5   with   increasing   numerical   values   indicating   a   higher   degree   of   coordination.  As  regards  the  second  dimension,  the  value  is  calculated  on  the  basis  of  the   mean  of  the  two  remaining  main  criteria  6  and  7.  Given  that  the  two  main  criteria  have  a   reciprocal   relationship   so   that   a   system   is   situated   halfway   between   the   poles   of   input   and   output   control   if   the   two   criteria   are   equally   realised,   the   values   are   standardised   before   the   mean   is   calculated.   The   value   expresses   which   of   the   two   modes   of   governance   have   a   stronger  influence  on  the  VET  system  in  question.         7.  Exemplary  results  from  previous  governance  workshops   An  international  comparsion  study  (Rauner  et.  al.  2010,  Rauner,  Wittig  2013)  investigated   the   dual   systems   of   VET   in   Denmark,   Switzerland,   Austria   and   Germany.   A   specific   fokus   of   the   study   was   the   assessment   of   their   governance   systems.   The   results   show   remarkable   differences   under   the   VET   systems   evaluated,   but   also   shows   that   evaluation   method   works   well   for   delivering   effective   research   results   and   supports   expert   focus   group   workshops.     The   positioning   of   the   four   countries   verifies   that   in   Germany   the   fragmention   of   governance   is   quite   strong   while   in   Denmark   and   in   Switzerland   there   is   a   remarkable   degree   of   coordination.   Also   Switzerland   with   its   pronounced   federalism   and   language   pluralism   has   a   well-­‐developed   and   coordinated   system   of   dual   vocational   education   and   training.  After  the  reforms  of  the  past  decade  Denmark  can  be  regarded  as  an  example  of   coordinated   output-­‐oriented   governance.   This   is   illustrated   by   the   fact   that   the   political   responsibility  is  concentrated  in  one  body.   To  some  extent  the  German  system  can  be  regarded  as  the  opposite  model  to  the  Danish   VET   system   (Cort   2005).   A   long   tradition   of   decentralisation   has   led   to   a   strongly    

9  

fragmented   governance   system,   as   is   already   shown   by   the   separation   of   the   legislative   powers  for  the  two  branches  of  vocational  education  and  training.  While  the  school  part  of   dual   apprenticeship   training   and   the   school-­‐based   VET   programmes   are   under   the   responsibility  of  the  states  (Länder),  the  federal  government  is  responsible  for  in-­‐company   training   within   dual   VET.   Finally,   the   domain   of   continuing   vocational   education   and   training  is  characterised  by  an  uncoordinated  variety  of  both  federal  and  state  regulations.   Like   Germany   and   Switzerland,   Austria   is   characterised   by   strongly   developed   federal   structures.   However,   contrary   to   Germany   the   responsibility   for   educational   policy   is   concentrated   at   the   federal   level,   and   this   applies   also   to   vocational   education.   This   allows   for   a   better   coordination   of   the   system   than   in   Germany.   The   implementation   of   VET   is   regulated  at  the  state  level,  and  the  Federal  Ministry  of  Education  is  the  supervisory  body   for  the  entire  education  system.  In  recent  years  a  number  of  reforms  were  implemented   that   followed   the   modern   principles   of   deregulation   and   decentralisation,   but   the   dominant  paradigm  is  still  juridical  and  bureaucratic.  The  diagramme  shows  results  of  the   assessment  workshops  under  of  the  four  types  of  Governance.     10

9

8,6

8,6 7,9

8

7,6 7,3

7,1

7

7

7,22

7 6,7

6,4

6,2

6,2 5,9

6 5,4

5,3

5 4,1

4,3

4 3,2

3,3

3

2

1 1. consistent legal framework

2. cooperation of the various bodies

3. innovation strategies

4. balance of relevant policy areas

5. allocation of strategic and operational functions

Diagramme  2:    Results  of  4  expert  focus  group  governance  workshops  under  stakeholders   and  the  evaluation  criteria  1.  upt  to  5.       With  VET  system  in  Denmark;  Switzerland  with  better  evaluation  results  than  Austria  and   Germany  (weakest  position)  (index:  first  column  Denmark,  second  column  Switzerland;   third  column  Austria,  fourth  column  Germany)      

10  

 

8.  Outlook  on  the  current  problems  within  Indian  Apprenticeship  and  the  need  for   Governance   Apprenticeship   in   India   means   a   system   of   training   in   which   an   employer   engages   a   person   as  an  apprentice  and  to  train  him/her  systematically  in  the  designated  trade  (there  are  over   30   trades   and   industrial   sectors)   (Roy   et.al.,   2014).   The   Indian   Apprenticeship   Act   (1961)   was  drawn  up  based  on  the  principles  of  ‘learning  by  earning’  and  ‘learning  by  doing’.  The   number  of  apprentices  has  remained  stagnant  and  has  not  increased  in  numbers  over  the   year.   Only   215,000   persons   are   undergoing   apprenticeship   training   against   a   seating   capacity  of  320,000  in  2008-­‐2009  (Directorate  General  of  Employment  and  Training  (DGET),   2009).       The  India  Apprenticeship  System  is  state  regulated  and  is  involving  manifold  stakeholders.   But   it   is   a   relatively   tiny   VET   system   compared   to   the   Indian   quantities.   Dominant   is   school   education   (227   million   pupils)   or   Technician   Vocational   Training   (1   million)   and   Higher   Education   (14   million).   Therefore   the   dual   model   has   huge   potential   insofar   while   at   the   side   of   the   formal   system   there   is   the   huge   informal   apprenticeship   system   (estimations   speak  of  20  million  novices  are  growing  up  their  expertise  on  an  informal  basis).     Further  details  on  the  current  status  of  the  formal  apprenticeship  is  provided  by  the  report   of  the  Ministry  of  Labour  and  Employment’s  (Mole  2011).  The  report  highlights  that,:   • The  intake  of  apprentices  into  industry  is  less  than  the  capacity,   • the  participation  rates  of  training  establishments  is  increasing,   • the  number  of  successful  apprentices  in  the  Trade  Test  has  increased,   • in  8  trade  areas  there  was  neither  intake  capacity  nor  enrolments  and   • in  16  trade  areas  intake  capacity  existed  but  there  were  no  enrolments.   The   report   states   that   there   is   high   potential   for   the   growing   up   of   the   numbers   of   the   Indian   apprenticeship’s.   But   this   only   realistic   when   more   parts   of   the   informal   could   be   formalised   and   increased   in   their   quality   and   output   but   based   on   new   ressources   for   minimum  allowances,  training  support  centres  etc..     Therefore   it   worth   to   study   and   discuss   some   of   the   difficulties   of   the   formal   apprenticeship  in  order  to  learn  about  strategic  turning  points.  First  policy  problem  area  is   to   overcome   and   to   counteract   towards   the   low   status   and   bad   image   of   apprenticeship   and   the   lack   of   involvement   of   employers   or   chambers   into   curriculum   design   and   the   examinations.   Also   the   not   yet   realised   non-­‐coverage   of   trades,   like   the   service   sector   as   another   apprentice   recruitment   potential.   All   this   calls   for   concerted   governance   action.   Even  when  there  are  still  difficulties  there  is  the  collective  energy  of  the  stakeholders  which   potentially  could  be  activated  by  financial  resources  and  collective  strategy.  This  could  help   the  system  to  overcome  difficulties  and  grow  again.     While   the   Indian   economy   is   embedded   in   fast   social   and   market   related   change   processes   also   the   training   models   need   quicker   adaptation   than   in   the   past.   This   needs   the   commitment   of   the   stakeholders   also   on   the   informal   side   of   the   national   Indian   economy.   Beside  the  rapidly  growing  service  sector  there  are  Asian  and  European  countries  who  may   outsource   technical   support   and   customer   services   to   India.     There   is   potential   growth   potential   in   the   Indian   economy   including   manufacturing,   ship   construction,   pharmaceuticals,   aviations,   biotechnology,   tourism,   retailing   and   information/communication  technologies.     Apprenticeships  is  regarded  as  a  big  part  of  a  much  broader  policy  thrust  to  improve  the   skill  levels  of  the  population  whilst  simultaneously  addressing  some  of  the  social,  economic   and   educational   problems   that   confront   India.   What   are   the   infrastructural   deficits   and   challenges   VET   apprenticeships?   There   are   manifold   deficits   and   problems   to   be   noted;    

11  

some   of   them   are:   lack   of   sufficient   well   trained   teachers   and   trainers,   lack   of   involvement   of  industrial  associations,  lack  of  accreditation  and  examination,  lack  of  workplace  curricula   (Mole  2011,  Roy  et.  al.  2014).     But   key   to   this   all   is   the   lack   of   effective   governance   models   in   place   that   help   to   structure   debates   about   apprentice   VET   on   regional   and   local   level   and   allows   to   develop   regional   VET   innovation   networks   (Attwell,   Deitmer   2000).   To   develop   the   Indian   apprenticeship   model   further   the   above   described   evaluation   approach   could   be   used   as   a   group   development  instruments  for  the  hand  of  the  stakeholders.  The  aim  would  be  to  access  the   current   status   of   governance   practises   by   involving   stakeholder   of   the   apprenticeship   system   and   to   convince   them   for   an   evaluation   of   the   current   state   of   the   art   and   to   identify  the  particular  weaknesses  and  hurdles  of  the  apprentice  cooperation.  This  with  the   intention  to  find  out  under  which  circumstances  the  cooperation  of  the  private  and  public   bodies  can  be  enhanced  and  developed  further.     Therefore   the   above   described   evaluation   tool   would   be   a   chance   to   deliver   for   a   first   diagnosis  of  the  current  cooperation  culture  and  also  to  allow  monitoring  of  running  pilot   projects  which  are  used  as  a  start  to  embetter  the  training  situation.  This  could  help  to  find   out  the  potential  of  giving  the  informal  apprenticeship  system  more  formal  elements  and   and  services.     But  still  there  is  too  little  information  about  the  informal  part  of  the  Indian  apprenticeships   which  by  now  are  not  yet  officially  registered  or  supported  by  any  kind  of  minimum  actions   or  project  or  programmes.  The  investigation  of  the  cooperation  potential  and  willingness  of   the  partners  to  build  for  cooperation  and  to  pilot  and  evaluate  minimum  support  actions   for   the   informal   students   (e.g.   implementation   of   basic   occupational   profiles,   work   place   curricula,   designating   and   teaching   of   trade   related   trainers   etc.)   could   be   a   start.   A   collective   strategy   by   involvement   of   the   key   stakeholders   needs   to   be   developed.   This   than   could   govern   the   change   process   and   allows   to   develop   an   intentional   strategy   by   using   different   view   points:   Industry,   Associations,   Schools,   Polytechnics,   Local   and   Regional  Administrations.       9.  Conclusions   The  main  argument  would  be  that  an  coordinated  and  occupation  based  VET  governance   model   delivers   for   some   more   advantages   compared   with   marked   or   state   oriented   governance  models.  The  strength  of  the  apprentices  models  and  the  prospected  rise  of  the   skilled   labour   market   segment   with   falling   figures   for   unskilled   and   low   skilled   labour   delivers   additional   arguments   for   the   apprenticeship   approach.   This   model   ensures   an   optimal  mix  of  individual  choices  and  collective  obligations.  These  are  based  on  regulated   training  standards  with  firm  level  flexible  implementation.  The  INAP  memorandum  by  the   INAP  commission  explains  what  it  would  mean  to  develop  apprenticeship  models,  like  the   one  in  India.  Following  the  work  of  the  INAP  commissions  on  which  some  of  these  quality   requirements  are  presented  (see  INAP  memorandum,  in:  Deitmer  et.al.  2013):     (1)  A  better  balance  between  an  national  and  regional  or  local  VET  policy.  This  would  mean   an   more   strategic   orientation   allocated   at   the   national   level   on   the   one   hand,   and   localisation  of  national  standards  with  adequate  room  for  manoeuvre  for  local  VET  agents   of  local  VET  practice  on  the  other.      

12  

(2)   A   limited   number   occupational   profiles   (Switzerland   or   Denmark   have   100   to   200   occupations  defined  not  over  350  as  in  Germany  or  Austria)  with  preferably  international   relevance   should   offer   guidance   to   trainees,   trainers   and   teachers.   The   curriculum   for   a   training  occupation  is  termed  and  integrated  plan  when  it  serves  as  a  basis  for  the  design   of  learning  processes  at  the  enterprise,  the  vocational  school  or  industrial  training  centre.     (3)   In-­‐company   training   must   be   organised   in   such   a   way   as   to   ensure   self-­‐financing   through   the   productive   work   of   the   trainees.   In   countries   with   developed   VET   systems   it   turned  out  that  this  condition  can  be  met.  On  average  of  the  training  costs  are  covered  or   even  exceeded  by  the  training  revenue.         (4)   Vocational   education   has   to   be   integrated   into   the   national   systems   of   education   to   enable  trainees  to  attain  a  university  entrance  qualification.  Here  Switzerland  is  an  example   of   best   practice,   since   90%   of   the   students   at   universities   of   applied   sciences   have     completed   a   dual   vocational   training   programme   before   their   studies.   This   can   help   to   enhance   the   attractiviness   of   the   VET   apprenticeship   system   and   to   overcome   image   problems  in  vocational  education  and  training.     (5)   It   is   advantegous   when   a   larger   proportion   of   the   enterprises   (INAP   speaks   of   ca.   30-­‐ 35%;   even   though   in   Countries   like   Germany   with   its   25   %   figures   this   still   could   be   improved)   have   to   be   willing   and   able   to   participate   in   modern   vocational   training.   Learning   in   instructive   work   processes,   reflected   work   experience,   is   one   of   the   key   essential  of  this  type  of  vocational  training.  In  modern  dual  vocational  training,    between   50  and  70%  of  the  training  time  are  assigned  to  learning  in  the  work  process.       The   question   remains   whether   an   integrated   development   strategy   for   sustainable   VET   governance   can   be   also   developed   for   countries   like   India   or   other   Asian   countries.   This   relates   also   to   the   key   point   in   how   far   the   mentioned   standards   and   governance   evaluation   tools   can   help   to   overcome   skill   shortages   but   also   bridge   knowledge   of   how   to   develop  the  right  decisions  in  order  to  move  forward  to  a  renaissance  of  apprenticeships  in   which  work  based  learning  (of  50  %  up  to  70%  of  the  training  time)  takes  place.       References: Arnold,  R.,  Gonon,  P.  (2006).  Einführung  in  die  Berufspädagogik,  Opladen:  Budrich   Deitmer,  L.;  Attwell,  G..  (2000)  Partnerships  and  networks  a  dynamic  approach  to  learning   in   global   regions.   In:   Barry   Nyhan,   Ludger   Deitmer,   Graham   Attwell   (2000)   (Eds.):   Towards  the  Learning  Region.  Education  and  Regional  Innovation  in  the  European  Union   and   the   United   States.   Luxemburg   Office   for   Official   Publications   of   the   European   Communities   Bertelsmann   Stiftung   (eds.)   (2009).   Steuerung   der   beruflichen   Bildung   im   internationalen   Vergleich.  Gütersloh:  Verlag  Bertelsmann  Stiftung.   Busemeyer  M.  R.,  Trampusch  C.  (eds.),  The  Political  Economy  of  Collective  Skill  Formation.   Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press,  2012. Clematide,  B.,  Dahl,  A.,  Vind,  A.,  Joergensen,  C.  H.  (2005).  Challenges  for  the  Danish  VET-­‐ system   –   on   the   path   towards   a   new   future   model.   Berufs-­‐   und   Wirtschaftspädagogik   online,   7.   http://www.bwpat.de/7eu/clematide_etal_dk_bwpat7.pdf.   Accessed   12   April   2007.  

 

13  

Cort,   P.   (2005).   The   Danish   Vocational   Education   and   Training   System.   Resource   document.   Danish   Ministry   of   Education,   Department   for   Vocational   Education   and   Training.   http://pub.uvm.dk/2005/VET/87-­‐603-­‐2524-­‐0.pdf.  Accessed  11  April  2007.   Deitmer,   L.   (2011a)   Building   up   of   innovative   capabilities   of   workers.   In:   Fostering   Enterprise:   The   Innovation   And   Skills   Nexus   -­‐   Research   Readings,   ED.:   Penelope   Curtin,   NCVER:  National  Centre  Vocational  Education  Research,  Adelaide   Deitmer,   L.   (2011b)   Quality   Criteria   for   Establishing   Work-­‐   Based   Learning.   IN:   An   Evaluation   of   In-­‐Company   Learning   Arrangements,   Tayo   Fashoyin,   Michele   Tiraboschi,   Pietro   Manzella,   Lisa   Rustico   (Eds.)   Productivity   Investment   In   Human   Capital   And   The   Challenge  Of  Youth  Employment,  Cambridge  Scholars  Publishing   Deitmer,   L.,   Hauschild,   U.,   Rauner,   F.   und   Zelloth,   H.,   (EDS.).   (2013)   The   Architecture   Of   Innovative  Apprenticeship.  Dordrecht:  Springer   DEITMER,   L.;   GERDS,   P..   (2002):   Developing   a   regional   VET   dialogue   on   vocational   education   and   training.   A   platform   for   bridging   between   VET   provision   and   private   organisational   needs.   Ed..:   Pekka   Kamärarainen,   Graham   Attwell,   and   Alan   Brown   Transformation   of   learning   in   education   and   training,   CEDEFOP   reference   series   37,   Luxembourg   Directorate   General   of   Employment   and   Training.   (2009).   Annual   Report   2008-­‐2009.   Ministry  of  Labour  and  Employment  (MOLE),  New  Delhi:  Government  of  India,  Ministry   of  Labour  and  Employment,  Survey  and  Study  Division.   Greinert,   W.-­‐D.   (1998).   Das   “deutsche”   System   der   Berufsausbildung.   Tradition,   Organisation,   Funktion.   3rd   edition.   Baden-­‐Baden:   Nomos.   http://labour.nic.in/annrep/annrep2008.htm INAP  (International  Network  on  Innovative  Apprenticeship).  Memorandum  ‘An  Architecture   for   Modern   Apprenticeships’.Standards   for   Structure,   Organisation   and   Governance.   INAP  Commission  “Architecture  Apprenticeship”,  April  2012.     Available  from  Internet:  http://www.inap.uni-­‐ bremen.de/dl/memorandum_inap_commission_architecture_apprenticeship_2012.pdf   [cited  2.1.2015].   Ministry  of  Labour  and  Employment  (MOLE)  (2011).Trade  Apprenticeship  Training  in  India   Under   Apprenticeship   Training   Scheme.   New   Delhi:   Government   of   India,   Ministry   of   Labour  and  Employment,  Survey  and  Study  Division.   Rashidi,   R.   (2013).   The   framework   for   effective   collaboration   between   public   institutions   and  private  industry  in  context  of  the  National  Dual  Training  System  (NDTS)  environment   in  Malaysia,  University  Tun  Hussein:  Jahor   Rauner,  F.;  Wittig,  W.  (2013).  Differences  in  the  Organisation  of  Apprenticeship  in  Europe:   Findings   of   a   Comparative   Evaluation   Study.   In:   Deitmer,   L.;   Hauschildt,   U.;   Rauner,   F.;   Zelloth,  H.  (eds).  The  Architecture  of  Innovative  Apprenticeship.  Dordrecht:  Springer,  pp.   243-­‐255.   Rauner,   F.;   Wittig,   W.;   Deitmer,   L.   (2010).   Plural   Administration   in   Dual   Systems   in   Selected   European   Countries.   In:   Rauner,   F.;   Smith,   E.   (eds).   Rediscovering   Apprenticeship:   Research  Findings  of  the  International  Network  on  Innovative  Apprenticeship.  Dordrecht:   Springer,  pp.  31-­‐43.  (Technical  and  Vocational  Education  and  Training  Series,  Vol.  11).   Roy,  B.  (2012).  ‘India’,  In  E.  Smith  &  R.  Brennan  Kemmis  (Eds).  Compilation  of  country  case   studies  for  the  ‘Possible  futures  for  the  Indian  Apprenticeships  system’  project.  Ballarat,   Australia:  University  of  Ballarat   Ryan,   P.   and   L.   Unwin   (2001),   ‘Apprenticeship   in   the   British   ‘training   market’,   National   Institute  Economic  Review,  178,  pp.  99-­‐114    

14  

         

 

15