Scientist American Behavioral - CiteSeerX

29 downloads 98 Views 138KB Size Report
Apr 8, 2007 - Thomas D. Beamish. Economic Sociology in the Next Decade and Beyond http://abs.sagepub.com/cgi/content/abstract/50/8/993. The online ...
American Behavioral Scientist http://abs.sagepub.com

Economic Sociology in the Next Decade and Beyond Thomas D. Beamish American Behavioral Scientist 2007; 50; 993 DOI: 10.1177/0002764207299350 The online version of this article can be found at: http://abs.sagepub.com/cgi/content/abstract/50/8/993

Published by: http://www.sagepublications.com

Additional services and information for American Behavioral Scientist can be found at: Email Alerts: http://abs.sagepub.com/cgi/alerts Subscriptions: http://abs.sagepub.com/subscriptions Reprints: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.nav Permissions: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav Citations (this article cites 56 articles hosted on the SAGE Journals Online and HighWire Press platforms): http://abs.sagepub.com/cgi/content/abstract/50/8/993#BIBL

Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

Economic Sociology in the Next Decade and Beyond

American Behavioral Scientist Volume 50 Number 8 April 2007 993-1014 © 2007 Sage Publications 10.1177/0002764207299350 http://abs.sagepub.com hosted at http://online.sagepub.com

Thomas D. Beamish University of California, Davis

This article assesses “Economic Sociology in the Next Decade and Beyond.” In addressing this broad thematic, as it relates to what some have called the new economic sociology, the article notes the “legacy effect” that a polemic with conventional economic conceptualizations has had on the recent reemergence and shape of this field, the relationship that the predominate schools of thought have to one another and the centrifugal tendencies they currently exhibit in this field, and the relationship this field of study currently has to general sociological theories and research streams. The article expressly argues that it is essential to the current and future relevance of the new economic sociology that it seek to bridge key concepts and ideas across methodologically and substantively distinct subfoci within its purview; enhance the theoretical continuity between its findings and theoretical insights and those that explain more generic sociological processes; and more explicitly theorize the role of agency, materiality, and the place of inequality in economic contexts, especially markets, as these are currently undertheorized in this field of study. Keywords: sociological theory; economic sociology; economic agency; economic institutions; economic inequality; markets; culture; interpretation; rationality

T

he task of this article is to address “Economic Sociology in the Next Decade and Beyond.” Specifically, the article assesses “where economic sociology has been” and “the contemporary state of economic sociology” and proffers a preference with regard to “where economic sociology should go in the future,” or at least where the author would like to see more directed energy spent in this field. In addressing this theme and these three broad questions, the article is organized around its answers. First, the article addresses the legacy a polemic with conventional economic models has had on the shape of scholarship in the field and whether continuing to argue with conventional economics is productive, counterproductive, or both. Next, the article outlines the contemporary centrifugal tendencies of this field and the relationship that its predominate schools of thought have to one another and to general sociological theories and research streams. Finally, the article concludes with some thoughts

Author’s Note: The author would like to thank Patrick Carol, Fred Block, and Vicki Smith for useful comments on earlier versions of this article. The opinions and judgments advanced in this article are the sole responsibility of the author. 993 Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

994 American Behavioral Scientist

and preferences regarding neglected theoretical aspects of economic sociology that require increased attention and improvement.

Where Has Economic Sociology Been? In answering where economic sociology has been, two issues indelibly mark its historical legacy and hence, in part, its current form. First, a polemic with classical and micro economics (hereafter conventional economics)1 that continues to haunt, invigorate, and in many respects organize the field. Second, the relationship the schools of thought that predominate within economic sociology have to one another and to general theoretical currents in sociology. Specifically, my attention will focus on economic sociological research and theory that has, of late, focused primarily on market dynamics, what might rightly be called the sociology of markets. Although this admittedly gives short shrift to overlapping interests—development studies, labor stratification, as well as work and occupations that could fall within and inclusive definition of “economic sociology” (more on this later)—the sociology of markets currently sits at the figurative center of what some have called the new economic sociology (Dobbin, 2004; Fligstein, 2002; Granovetter, 1992; Guillén, 2002; Zelizer, 2002).

The Reemergence of Economic Sociology The recent rise of the new economic sociology (hereafter simply economic sociology) as a distinct arena of study with a principal focus on modern market contexts reflects a view change that took hold in the 1980s (Smelser & Swedberg, 1994). The change corresponded with movement, primarily among organizational sociologists and allied scholars, from internally focused accounts of firm dynamics to those that increasingly focused on the environmental contexts within which any given corporate form was embedded (see classics Hannan & Freeman, 1977; Meyer & Rowan, 1977; Pfeffer & Salancik, 1978; Williamson, 1975).2 Markets became a central focus of attention as they are the primary location within which modern states, firms, and individuals involved in economic activities conduct themselves. As sociologists drew conclusions from their “dirty” empirical research and compared them to the “clean” models posited by conventional economists, their answers departed from economic orthodoxy (Hirsch, Michaels, & Friedman, 1987). This brought back into focus an argument that had lain largely dormant within this subfield for some time—the philosophical divide between classical economic and sociological accounts of economy. The philosophical roots of the polemic are found in the social commentary and writings of early political economists Adam Smith, David Ricardo, Jeremy Bentham, John Stuart Mill, and Karl Marx. Their legacy is further reflected in the works of both Weber (1922/1968) and Durkheim (1984) and later Karl Polanyi (1947, 1957b), who also debated contemporaries in the Austrian School of Economics (Hayek, 1994; Menger, 1950; Mises, 1980).

Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

Beamish / Economic Sociology in the Next Decade and Beyond 995

Simultaneously, the polemic with conventional economics and increased attention to market formation by sociologists also reflected rapidly changing economic contexts—especially salient was the successful growth of East Asian states, markets, and firms—and the inadequacy of classical and microeconomic models (as well as their primary alter “dependency theory”) to explain them. In contrast to voluntaristic and instrumental logics characteristic of conventional economic models, organizational and network (Baker, 1984; Biggart & Hamilton, 1992; Burt, 1983; Granovetter, 1985; White, 1981) as well as development scholars (Berger, 1986; Castells, 1992; Gereffi, 1989, 1994) observed the central part that structure and culture played in the formation of markets, the shape of industries, and the behavior of firms (Hamilton & Biggart, 1988). The timely publication of Granovetter’s (1985) programmatic statement “Economic Action and Social Structure” provided the context for a theoretical realignment. Granovetter emphasized the social embeddedness of all economic action and explicitly broke with what he termed, borrowing from Wrong (1961), the oversocialized views associated with Parson’s legacy and the undersocialized views of conventional economic models. Along with Granovetter’s piece, seminal work by the likes of White (1981), Burt (1982), Hamilton and Biggart (1988), and Zelizer (1979, 1988) worked to galvanize the reemergence of economic sociology. With the publication of Smelser and Swedberg’s (1994) Handbook of Economic Sociology, the die was cast; the tome worked to institutionalize the new economic sociology as a distinct arena of study. By January 2001, economic sociology was officially recognized and granted section status by the American Sociological Association.

The Polemic This attenuated history renders the central position that an ongoing polemic with conventional economics has taken in economic sociology old and new. The current axis of this polemic reflects both different ways of approaching similar problems as well as the tone and place of conventional economic conceptualizations in contemporary society. In answering basic questions about the workings of the formal economy, such as how economic actors coordinate with others who likewise seek to interact and exchange goods and services, conventional economics’ answer is straightforward and wonderfully parsimonious, if to most sociologists woefully undersocialized market dynamics involve abstractly conceived autonomous individuals coming together to transact in interactions governed by fluctuations in price. When the highest bidder succeeds, the market clears. Imbalances in offers to buy and sell provoke changes in price (i.e., supply), providing markets with what economists view as their order producing equilibrium (Eatwell, Milgate, & Newman 1987). Price, as a reflection of marginal utility, is the mechanism through which Adam Smith’s invisible hand works its magic. The normative aspects emerge from the conventional economic belief that pure market dynamics reflect an emergent, naturally occurring order that is the most efficient means for allocating goods and services in

Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

996 American Behavioral Scientist

society. If free market conditions are to reign and Pareto efficient outcomes are to be realized, they must be rid of the social distortions that disrupt their natural tendencies toward efficiency. “Sociability,” in the form of social ties, norms of reciprocity, and familial obligations, among other social processes, has no constructive place in this conceptualization, where the efficient distribution of goods and services is the end game. In this view, the economy as a theoretical abstraction is distinct from the other elements that characterize society. In a word, the economy is purposefully reified. Economic theory has not stopped with the economy, however, as evidenced in the work of prominent contemporary economists (Becker, 1976, 1996; Hirshleifer, 1985). Increasingly, over time, conventional economic models have colonized a larger and larger portion of the social scientific commons as their assumptions and models have been imported into political science (Chong, 2000; Popkin, 1979) and sociology (Coleman, 1990, 1994; Hechter & Kanazawa, 1997). In extreme examples, economists posit their model to be both a description of how (all) human societies materially (re)produce themselves as well as a general theory of the underlying motivations that unite all human exchange and by extension are the bedrock for all human interaction (Hirshleifer, 1985). In this fiat, individual self-interest and utility maximization govern human behavior whether economic or not. As aggregate abstractions, social structure and cultural elements, at best, are viewed as indirect influences on individual actor choice, a patina on an otherwise deeper set of selfinterested motivations (Becker & Murphy, 2000). Over the past two decades, as economists have found their universalistic suppositions concerning actor motives routinely violated (Akerlof, 2001), the cutting edge of economics has moved increasingly toward the study of special conditions and “special cases” (Akerlof, 1980; Akerlof & Yellen, 1985). For example, Akerlof, Kahenman, and Schelling have been awarded recent Nobel Prizes for complicating and improving on conventional economic suppositions, those specifically being methodological individualism and comprehensive rationality, and thus strengthening understandings of economic decision making. Economists, with the help of cognitive theory (Kahenman, Slovic, & Tversky, 1982), game theory (Schelling, 1960), and even organizational theory (Stiglitz, 1999), have sought to understand not simply economic contexts and transactions, but broadly the systematic basis of irrationality and “miscalculation” (Kahenman & Tversky, 1973, 2000) and even failed reform (cf., Stiglitz, 2002). Although this research seemingly seeks to bridge the substantive divide between a social view of economy and a utility maximizing one— that is, one that admits markets are real places reflective of socially embedded actors—it is against the continued backdrop of a reified set of assumptions that conventional economics compares and contrasts its findings and recommends its remedies and on which its normative prescriptions continue to be based. The empirical study of economic contexts by sociologists, the conclusions they have drawn, and the theories they have developed have on rare occasion complimented (Coleman, 1994), mostly complicated, and even inverted conventional economic

Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

Beamish / Economic Sociology in the Next Decade and Beyond 997

assumptions and claims (Fligstein, 2001; Granovetter, 1985; White, 1981, 2002). Some sociologists have reacted vituperatively to conventional economic preferences, models, and policy prescriptions, claiming that far from promoting efficiency and uniform prosperity they promote inequality and socially “inefficient” outcomes because they ignore empirical reality in favor of a reified theoretical object (Block, 1996; Braverman, 1998; Edwards, 1978, 1979; Marglin, 1974; Molotch, 1990; Perrow, 1972). Still others have pointed out that their argument with conventional economics is more than just a theoretical difference of opinion because economic presumptions and thus preferences are also practiced by governments, private firms, and world governance bodies such as the World Bank, the International Monetary Fund, and the World Trade Organization (Bourdieu, 1999, 2001). In short, they claim, conventional economic models are both academic theories as well as well funded, rewarded, regulated, and enforced by governmental institutions and powerful economic actors that deem them preferable and justify them with claims of their “naturalness” (Block, 1994, 1996). Likewise, conventional economists strongly differ from a sociological view that approaches economic contexts more agnostically. For a majority of economic sociologists, exchange relations, like other social affairs, reflect inherently social processes and relations that may or may not reflect or promote the “truly efficient” exchange and distribution of goods and services. On this, economic sociologists are not unified. Some believe social relations promote efficiency by lowering the cost of transactions (Uzzi, 1996, 1999; see also institutional economist Williamson, 1985), whereas others find that “efficiency” is an inadequate term when survival is the goal, preferring “effectiveness” instead (Fligstein, 2001). Still others view efficiency as irrelevant, because markets reflect elite control as evidenced in lending practices, interlocking directorates, and the general oligopoly of the current economic system (Braverman, 1998; Edwards, 1978, 1979; Marglin, 1974; Perrow, 2002). For sociologists, “efficiency” tends to be an empirical question not a shared assumption or even (necessarily) the aim of their research. Although amongst themselves economic sociologists may disagree on many items, most do not adhere to conventional economic suppositions or its normative agenda. For better and for worse, then, the polemic with conventional economists has lent economic sociology a good bit of its current form (Swedberg, 1987) and much of its current energy. The argument is a substantively based one that this author believes should continue, albeit in a modified form and not for its own sake. This may surprise some, as of late there seems a chorus of voices objecting to a continued dispute with conventional economics, claiming economic sociology should “move on.” Yet in defense of the argument with conventional economics, this is not a purely rhetorical exercise, a desire to spearhead an intellectual insurgency, nor reducible to something as crass as career building opportunism (e.g., Postrel, 2005). What is more, it need not take form as a condemnation of commercial endeavor, monetization, and cost accounting, that is, modern markets or an equally naive celebration of social

Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

998 American Behavioral Scientist

spheres where caring and substantive concerns supposedly reign supreme. A “hostile worlds” view, whether presented via economic assumptions or through simplistic diatribes against them, is equally reductionist and unproductive (see Zelizer, 2005a; this issue). Rather, economic sociology’s argument with conventional economics should be rooted in the economic contexts that practitioners observe, not in reified distinctions that reflect conventional economic claims. Economic sociologists have shown empirically that economic relations do indeed involve many of the aspects that typify “formal economic” considerations. However, they have also found that the same economic contexts involve a great deal more than the ideal typifications operationalized in conventional economic accounts. Indeed, economic contexts, even modern markets, must include more than self-interested utility maximization as economic exchange like any other kind cannot be based solely upon it (Abolafia, 1996; Biggart & Beamish, 2003). When analytically decomposed, sociologists have repeatedly shown economic contexts to be relational, to require a modicum of intersubjectivity, and to reflect trust producing social ties that permit the material production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services to proceed. For example, Beamish and Biggart (2005a; see also Biggart & Delbridge, 2004) questioned the contemporary reification of “market dynamics” in economic sociology and related scholarship as limiting to how economic relations (broadly conceived) are conceptualized. They suggest instead that sociologists embrace a more robust notion of “exchange relations” to characterize economic transaction that can embrace both prototypical market exchanges but also other coconstitutive forms of social and material transfer (see Polanyi, 1957a). Exchange, as conceived by Max Weber (1922/1968), is a “voluntary agreement involving the offer of any sort of present, continuing, or future utility in exchange for utilities of any sort offered in return.” Exchange can involve money, goods, and/or services but can also reflect less tangible elements like respect, reciprocity, obligation, duty, and even moral convictions (Polanyi 1957a, 1957b). Use of exchange relations better accommodates the full range of social interactions, social institutions, and social structures characteristic of social worlds, including market-based ones. Pursuing a more robust notion of economy, as for example demonstrated through a focus on exchange relations, would provide economic sociology the means to celebrate its theoretical diversity while simultaneously provide a context for the pursuit of greater theoretical depth and coherence. It would also push economic sociology to move well beyond the limitations that accompany reified distinctions such as those that often accompany accounts of the “formal economy” and “market dynamics.” This is because, as the best economic sociology has shown time and again, the formal economy is itself informal in its actual operation; individuals rely on social ties, ad hoc solutions, and habits of the mind and heart to make so-called formal exchange work (see Molotch, 1990).

Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

Beamish / Economic Sociology in the Next Decade and Beyond 999

The Contemporary State of Economic Sociology On the contemporary state of economic sociology, three significant issues emerge that are related to the foregoing discussion. These are its lack of a galvanizing yet inclusive theoretical “centerpiece,” its contemporary analytic divisions and the relations that characterize those divisions, and its rapport with broader sociological streams of thought and theory. Addressing each of these requires that I collapse the contemporary state of economic sociology with my comments concerning where I would prefer more attention to be paid within it, as my preferences reflect my view of trends (or lack there of). Likewise, my stated preferences for the future are threefold. They involve the new economic sociology paying greater attention and better theorizing agency, materiality, and inequality in the contexts it studies.

Searching for a Substantive Center Thus far, I have argued that a polemic with conventional economics has played a central role in the form and directions that economic sociology has taken and is taking. Yet this ongoing argument is not as clearly oppositional as it may first appear; whereas economists and economic sociologist certainly disagree on the basis of economic transaction, they have tended to agree on what requires explanation. That is, while arguing over what is salient in any given market context, economic sociologists have typically prima facie accepted conventional economic distinctions that set off the “formal economy,” such as markets, from other social worlds (Krippner, 2001; Polanyi, 1957a; Zelizer, 2002). Accepting this distinction largely reflects the place of conventional economic assumptions in industrial societies. That the economy is viewed as autonomous from society is “taken for granted” by economists, certainly, but this view is also mobilized by business leaders and the general public and has been explicitly (Coleman, 1994; Parsons & Smelser, 1956) and implicitly (see Krippner’s [2001] critique) operationalized as such by economic sociologists. In short, conventional economic suppositions about market behavior, as a social construct, has become a societal, that is, cultural assumption. The distinction is something economic sociologists should study, not accept or assume. Indeed, this very assumption has put economic sociology in the unenviable position of endlessly defending and justifying its claims but also at times its very existence. The burden of endlessly justifying claims, building arguments around the denial of conventional economic presumptions, and yet arguing on a terrain that is defined largely by its substantive adversary has indeed put economic sociology in a tough spot. This is where criticisms levied against continuing an argument with conventional economics holds merit; shared antipathy for conventional economic suppositions is not enough (see Fligstein, 2001; Swedberg, this issue). Economic sociology requires its own bulkhead or bulkheads and must define them in terms native to it, not those defined by conventional economics.

Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

1000 American Behavioral Scientist

Within and Between Of course, where economic sociology is going reflects more than its relationship to conventional economics. Economic sociology’s future direction(s) is equal parts reflective of the relations that prevail between its predominate analytic strategies as well as their individual and collective relationship to the broad theoretical streams that define sociology in general. As a field of study, economic sociology reflects three primary substantive axes. The axes to which I make reference include micromacro, agency-structure, and interpretation3-network dimensions. Obviously, no single one of these axes constitutes the basis for any given study. Rather, linkages across these are the rule. Specifically, economic sociology has characteristically pursued analysis that highlights macro-structural-network, macro-structural-institutional, and micro-structural-network aspects of economic contexts. With a good bit less frequency has economic sociology approached economic contexts as micro, agential, and interpretation-based, assessing them as sociocultural arenas reflective of intersubjectivity, social process, and meaning reproduction. Before moving on, this point deserves attention. More than a decade ago, Zukin and DiMaggio (1990, p. 3) identified at least four types of “embeddedness” including structural, cognitive, cultural, and political types, of which the last three reflect predominantly cultural and meaning based elements. These are aspects of economic sociology that could be markedly improved upon (I take this up in more detail below). Macro and micro structural approaches have emphasized such matters as underlying roles, status hierarchies, and dependencies that characterize markets and fields of economic actors and the competitive advantages that accrue and that predict outcomes (Baker, 1984; Burt, 1992; Dobbin & Dowd, 1997, 2000; Freeman, Carroll, & Hannan, 1983; Pfeffer & Salancik, 1978; Podolny, 1994). Cultural and institutionalist approaches view economic contexts as socially constructed affairs. Cultural arguments emphasize the meaning-filled and process-oriented nature of economic contexts (Abolafia, 1996; Biggart, 1989; DiMaggio, 1994; Spillman, 1999; Zelizer, 2005b; Zukin & DiMaggio, 1990). Institutional arguments, primarily macro, emphasize stable forms of meaning, such as those that underlie law and regulation or those reflected in organizational forms, as structural influences (Dobbin, 1994; Fligstein, 1990; Hamilton, 1994). The result of these very different views of economic context— and the many theoretical subdivisions that further describe each general approach— has been a good bit of centrifugal rather than centripetal energy. Economic sociology has spun ever outward as sociologists have investigated new cases and gained new insights that reinforce their differing views and/or their different couplings of these basic substantive axes. Clearly, the current lack of theoretical center in economic sociology that can accommodate its theoretical diversity while simultaneously allowing for the pursuit of greater theoretical depth and coherence flows from the substantive differences that characterize its practitioners. For example, the study of culture and interpretation is

Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

Beamish / Economic Sociology in the Next Decade and Beyond 1001

centered on meaning and meaning production, which is necessarily discursive, categorical, and experiential. Whereas more structurally oriented network analysts (Baker & Faulkner, 1990; Burt, 1987, 1992; Granovetter, 1985; Podolny, 1993) emphasize an anticategorical imperative in which the attributes of actors (race, class, gender) are rejected in favor of their relative roles and positions as well as a rejection of either normative or interpretivist explanations of social action resulting from network position (Emirbayer & Goodwin, 1994, pp. 1414-1416). To blame this on epistemological differences alone, however, would be reductionist. Ironically, the lack of crossover and extensive exchange also flows from professional networks themselves and the meanings they attach to what is and is not legitimate research, given one’s expertise and substantive emphases. Straying into adjacent arenas of study can open one to criticism from all perspectives and thus scholars, especially young ones, seldom do so. In contrast, as economic sociology’s empirical work has progressed, such as that on networks, ecologies and institutional fields, and culture and interpretation it has become increasingly apparent that alone, none of these theoretical reductions will suffice (cf., Baum & Powell, 1995; Fligstein, 1995; Granovetter, 1992, 2002; Powell, 1998; Swaminathan & Carroll, 2000). In light of advancements, it is most productive to think of social structure, cultural constructions, and with them interpretation (in the broadest sense) as coconstitutive. Hence, the cross-fertilization of the earlier identified axes is critical to a thorough deepening of sociological theories of economic contexts. The point: Whereas all the centripetal energy in economic sociology is certainly a sign of a great deal of researcher enthusiasm and a positively growing field, it would seem an excellent moment to pursue theoretical synthesis. No doubt, this would both improve the overall explanatory power and coherence of economic sociology’s theory.

A Conversation With the “Outside” Along with the deepening of theory through greater synthesis, there is a comparable need for economic sociology to open its “boundaries” and better integrate outside streams that bear on its central questions and interests. That is, on the balance, the new economic sociology’s conversation with the “outside” could be more intense and sustained. Practitioners have tended to remain firmly ensconced in the literatures of “fellow travelers.”4 Specifically, three aspects of economic contexts are both undertheorized in contemporary economic sociology and important to more complete understandings of them. They are the place of agency, materiality, and inequality in economic contexts generally and markets specifically. Agency in Economy To my comments thus far, which have throughout been entwined with both stated preferences and opinion, I would add that the new economic sociology should give

Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

1002 American Behavioral Scientist

greater weight to the role of individual agency. At the micro level, network analysis has been clearly dominant. It has provided a strong view of what is undeniably a central aspect of any economy or market—its network structure. Yet given its theoretical bases, network analysis has not—indeed cannot—fully developed a theory of market place settings as eminently social ones, inhabited by intelligent actors who reflect on their own actions and the actions of others in inherently cultural and political contexts through mutually held understandings as well as relational ties (Fligstein, 1996). As an aside, this is one reason conventional economics, and for that matter rational choice models, have been so seductive at this level of explanation. Conventional economic accounts overstate the individual actor and in doing so lend the individual the chimera of (potential) complete control. Whereas a sociological account would indeed involve less unrestrained choice (Bourdieu, 1977; Giddens, 1986, 1990; Sewell, 1992), the new economic sociology could do better developing the role of agency in economic contexts. Outside of a handful of works at this level of analysis (Abolafia, 1996; Beamish & Biggart, 2005b; Biggart, 1989; Biggart & Beamish, 2003; Bourdieu, 2002; Callon, 1998; Smith, 1989; Zelizer, 1994), sociological approaches to economy have not typically afforded the individual the luxury of seeing themselves planning and acting, given the social forces they have described. The new economic sociology needs to if it wants to both present stronger theories of economic action as well as be taken seriously outside its own professional circles by folks (including each of us!) who believe they are “agents” and who are, in some measure, undeniably so. In this, the new economic sociology need not start from scratch. There are excellent theoretical exemplars that address agency in context that are underappreciated in the mainstream of the field. For example, Weber’s (1922/1968) program stressing interpretation (see also Swedberg 2007); pragmatist thought (Cooley, 1913; James, 1908; Mead, 2001); and interpretivists such as Garfinkel (1952, 1967) Goffman (1959, 1962), Strauss (1978), and Fine (1984, 1996); Shumpeter’s (1934) work on entrepreneurialism; as well as recent theoretical work on robust action and cultural pragmatics (Alexander, 2004; Bourdieu, 1977; Emirbayer & Goodwin, 1994; Emirbayer & Mische, 1998; Fligstein, 2001; Padgett & Ansell, 1992; Sewell, 1992) all provide the basis for a sociologically inspired view of agency in economic contexts. Likewise, the European Conventions School—a range of approaches that spring from common assumptions—represents a subjectivist approach to economic order that explicitly seeks to theorize agency within constraints (Beckert, 2002; for reviews, see Biggart & Beamish, 2003; Boltanski & Chiapello, 1999; Favereau, 2002; Gomez & Jones, 2000; Thévenot, 1994, 1998; Wilkinson, 1997). Collectively, these approaches are suggestive of the directions an approach to economic sociology sensitive to micro, interpretation, and agency. These theorists tend to share in a view of agency that finds it embedded and thus recursively related to social structure. Coordinated social action, economic or otherwise, these theories inform us, reflects individuals who intend to be “rational” given socially constructed

Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

Beamish / Economic Sociology in the Next Decade and Beyond 1003

and intersubjectively shared norms and assumptions and who achieve coordination via active not passive engagement. That is, rules and norms are not merely followed, they are reproduced or better “refashioned” through engagement in ways that typically result in (relative) social stability that nonetheless inherently involves some level of uncertainty whose resolution is the driver of differing levels of social change. Resolving uncertainty through social negotiation provides the dynamism behind social process (Biggart & Beamish, 2003). This should be a bigger part of how economic sociology understands economy, as an emergent process, not a static field of relations. Materiality in Economy Again, economic sociology claims as its domain the study of the social processes that structure how human societies materially produce, distribute, and consume goods and services. Yet explicit attention to the role of materiality has been largely absent from economic sociological analysis. Indeed, attending to the materiality of institutions is an aspect that sociology, in general, continues to struggle over (Pinch, 2003). Science and Technology Studies (STS) with its attention to the nexus of social, technical, and material aspects of systems or “sociotechnical assemblages,” has made inroads that hold considerable overlap with economic sociology’s stated interest and that could deepen its explications. Likewise, environmental sociology has explored “materiality” and has done so in relation to economic systems. Yet its focus has differed from that of economic sociology. While economic sociology has concentrated on the composition of economic relations to better understand the bases for economic transactions, environmental sociology has focused on the composition of economic systems to better understand the ramifications of economic relations for environmental sustainability. STS scholar Weibe Bijker (1987), for example, developed the notion of technological frame to capture the interrelated nature of concepts, techniques, and material artifacts. According to Bijker, technological frames reflect both the “techniques employed by a community in its problem solving” (p. 168) and the technologies too. Problem solving, thus operationalized, recognizes that the trials themselves and the solutions generated reflect both human subjectivity and the material technologies on hand that channel that subjectivity. Likewise, Hughes (1983) showed that the development of the electrical supply system in the United States, far from representing simply a superior technology as conventional conceptualization of innovation and economic transformation often presume, required a powerful system building bricoleur. Edison’s success in initially replacing the system of gas illumination in New York City, backed by a politically potent union of gas lamp lighters, with that of an electrical light infrastructure, was an interwoven process involving both social, technical, and technological (i.e., material) elements. As an entrepreneur, Edison’s success reflected his ability to knit together a network of powerful supporters and functionally adequate technologies that with time came to dominate the energy sector

Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

1004 American Behavioral Scientist

(see also Hargadon & Douglas, 2001; McGuire & Granovetter, 1998). Hughes added that whereas current sociotechnical assemblages5 may appear retrospectively “stable,” this is an illusion that reflects their power to maintain their viability in the face of ubiquitous and hostile forces. Challenger assemblages are a constant threat to the continued stability of an existent sociotechnical network (Callon, 1992; Hughes, Pinch, & Bijker, 1987; Latour & Porter, 1996; Law & Callon, 1997). STS scholars, then, view sociotechnical systems as embodying a heterogeneous network of elements including social networks, culture, and institutions but also obdurate material-technological implements and resources that are simultaneously involved in any social system as “actors” in their own right. Each aspect, whether human or otherwise, is approached as inherently political; materiality expresses purpose insofar as it changes outcomes (Winner, 1987). In brief, for STS scholarship, the part of contingency and the power to institutionalize a set of sociotechnical relations is central in the preservation (or dismantling) of any given sociotechnical system (Callon & Law, 1989; Latour & Woolgar, 1986), including economic ones (Callon, 1998). Environmental sociologists also investigate material relations. As with economic sociologists, “the economy” is conceived by environmental sociologists as a societal system for the collective production and distribution of resources. However, their focus on these relations differs: environmental sociologists seek to understand the material-ecological and social ramifications of the economic systems they study. Approached in this manner, “the economy” is more than the relations that describe human-to-human transactions alone; those relations are necessarily preceded and followed by human-to-environmental interactions reflected in both the withdrawal and the inevitable addition of "resources" that result from all material transformations (i.e., as specified by the first and second law of thermodynamics [Schnaiberg, 1980]). Environmental sociologists, then, view the economy in more explicitly materialistic terms: it is the primary point of translation between society and the environment (base, waste repository, and living space). Currently there are two principal positions within environmental sociology that present vastly different views of “the economy.” Both, however, agree that the economy is a crucible for environmental change (i.e., problems and solutions). One group of environmental sociologists characterizes society–environment relations as inherently environmentally destructive (Catton, 1980; Foster, 1999, 2002; Logan & Molotch, 1987; Molotch, 1976; O'Connor, 1994; Schnaiberg, 1980; Schnaiberg & Gould, 2000). Capitalist economic logic rewards economic actors—firms and individuals—who degrade the ecological or material “commons” to increase their individual capital accumulation. Given the competitive nature of global capitalism, failure to do so would threaten profitability and hence survival: competition amongst corporations constrains managers and promotes the externalization of ecological and social costs. Governments and workers likewise are also constrained from taking action as they are dependant on firms for tax revenues and jobs. Because this group of environmental sociologists views the global economy as inherently competitive, expansionistic, and ecologically destructive, they have labeled their view the “treadmill of

Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

Beamish / Economic Sociology in the Next Decade and Beyond 1005

production thesis” (hereafter TPT (Schnaiberg, 1980; Schnaiberg & Gould, 2000)). They contend that an exchange value conception of nature (Molotch, 1976), upon which capitalism is based, is fundamentally at odds with long term environmental sustainability. From this perspective, society and the environment are in an enduring conflict that bodes poorly for our collective futures. In contrast to TPT, recent proponents of the “ecological modernization thesis” (hereafter EMT (Mol, 1995, 2001; Mol, Lauber, & Liefferink, 2000; Mol & Sonnenfeld, 2000; Spaargaren, Mol, & Buttel, 2000)) posit in technological improvements a move towards the dematerialization and thus increasing sustainability of economic production, not “ecological overshoot” (Catton, 1980). Through what they term the second industrial revolution, EMT contends that industrial advances, mainly technological, are already available, will soon be available, or will be invented in the near future if natural market incentives are promoted by enlightened governments and public pressure. Once the incentives of market capitalism are set free from monopoly and malfeasance, they claim, a “natural capitalism” is sure to arise (Hawken, Lovins, & Lovins, 2000). Green purchasing, corporate performance certificates, such as ISO 14000, and promulgation of the precautionary principle, among a host of initiatives, provide the pretext for the ecological modernization of production. EMT claims that TPT is at best utopist and at worst defeatist, missing the incredible technological transformation taking place that has the capacity to transform economic production and thus society's “triple bottom line” —economic prosperity, environmental quality, and social equality. In response, TPT theorists counter that the gains that are trumpeted by EMT do not reflect free market mechanisms but coercive state regulation and that the “dematerialzation trends” noted by EMT, when rigorously analyzed, are not sustainable and involve more of the same: negative environmental and social externalizations (Pellow, Schnaiberg, & Weinberg, 2000; York, Rosa, & Dietz, 2003). In brief, both STS and environmental sociologists are involved in analyses and lively debates that hold important implications for a more fully articulated understanding of the “the economy” than typically mobilized in the new economic sociology. By crossing over, economic sociology could benefit from overlapping research traditions such as STS and Environmental Sociology. Furthermore, in doing so, STS, environmental sociology, and the new economic sociology could enrich one another in ways that would expand and complement existent research streams and generate a more robust account of economic relations. Inequality in Markets Although inequality, both in terms of power and access to needed opportunities and resources, takes center stage in traditions that overlap with economic sociology (e.g., political economy, development studies, labor studies, and work and occupations), it is rarely forefronted in the contemporary emphasis on market contexts. To be sure, power and dependency have been extensively theorized in macro and structural accounts of economic sociology, yet too often its exercise, especially its basis and

Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

1006 American Behavioral Scientist

the specific ramifications of its use, remain formless when represented through institutions, exclusionary networks, or couched in terms of generalized competition amongst commercial firms. This seems odd. If economic sociology’s mission is to understand systems of production, consumption, and distribution, then an interest in systemic aspects of inequality in these processes are elemental to this mission. Discrimination reflected in economic processes against the poor, women, minorities, and even the physically unattractive are basic, some claim essential aspects of the “formal economy.” This despite its irrational, nonoptimizing waste of human capital (Molotch, 1990; Perrow, 1972). For example, research on women in national as well as international and global markets has led critical labor scholars to argue that women’s labor has been systematically exploited as both free labor in domestic contexts and low-wage labor in the commercial sector. This, they claim, in part, has laid the basis for both the industrialization of the West (Engels, 1902; Kessler-Harris & Levenson, 1982; Matthaei, 1982) and the expansion of markets into parts of the developing world (Boserup, 1970; Brecher & Costello, 1994; Cheng & Hsuing, 1992; Enloe, 1990; Escobar, 1995; Faber, 1993; Parrado & Zenteno, 2001). Likewise, critical labor and development scholars have found that experience and life chances also systemically differ by race, ethnic, and class background. The lesson: Market relations, like social relations more generally, reflect social structures, cultural norms, beliefs, and affinities that systematically advantage some over others (Appelbaum & Bonacich, 2000; Milkman, 1987; Ridgeway, 1997; Treiman & Roos, 1983). This is yet another reason a naturalized and detached “formal economy” is such a powerful and obfuscating distinction and, perhaps, why inequality has not been vigorously pursued in the new economic sociology. Inequality is not viewed, as evidenced by the lack of attention paid to it, as basic to the logic of formal economic contexts as conventionally defined. Yet partitioning of the economy in such a way does not acknowledge (i.e., “price”) a great deal of what comprises economic process and in so doing ignores the bases of “the economy” as a real set of relations and experiences. Again, economic sociologists should not go along with such a restricted definition; with greater frequency, the new economic sociology should address the place of inequality, materiality, and agency in economic process.

Conclusion In reflecting on the three questions that organized this year’s American Sociological Association (ASA)–invited panel, “Economic Sociology in the Next Decade and Beyond,” and my answers to them, I have argued a handful of points. First, in relation to where economic sociology has come from, I made the case that it reflects a legacy, recently revived, that while exacting a price has also provided the form and impetus for a newfound interest in economic sociology. The argument has deep

Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

Beamish / Economic Sociology in the Next Decade and Beyond 1007

substantive roots that are not easily ignored and in many ways should not be. Simply put, conventional economic theory and concepts violate much of what in the past would have been called economic sociology and what contemporary economic sociologists have found underlies exchange: social contexts along with autonomy, embedded ties along with self-interest, substantive as well as instrumental concerns, intentional not comprehensive rationality, satisficing not maximizing behavior, socially constructed worlds not naturally occurring or genetically encoded ones, and so forth. Nonetheless, whereas I argued that the new economic sociology should continue to dialogue with conventional economic assumptions and market-organizing principles, this is not a call to arms; nor is it, admittedly, enough of a basis for a field of study. Specifically, to strengthen its foundation and hence its claims, I made the case that the new economic sociology should seek to more affirmatively bridge its internal divisions as well as more consistently seek to link its findings to general sociological streams of thought and theory. Most important, perhaps, along with this movement toward synthesis, economic sociology should also seek to define its basic motives and rationale for its analyses. Economic sociology should not accept the distinction rampant in conventional economics and implicitly in a great deal of economic sociology that the formal economy is somehow set off from other social and cultural “worlds.” A hostile worlds view, as so eloquently and repeatedly argued by Viviana Zelizer (2002, 2005a, 2005b), is not a productive distinction, as it reflects a reified not empirical distinction. I also argued that to improve the explanatory power of its theory, the new economic sociology should more explicitly articulate the place of agency, materiality, and inequality in economic contexts. To its credit, the new economic sociology has produced very strong scholarship as it has, over the past two decades, focused inward and developed the tools and theory to address the complexities of economic contexts as they empirically present themselves. Yet by both bridging its substantive divisions and more frequently connecting its findings to general theoretical streams, economic sociology would advance still stronger explanations. These steps would also have the simultaneous effect of ridding economic sociology of a most vexing distinction, the reified and hostile worlds view of economic and social spheres. In the final analysis, the social and behavioral repertoires that underlie and animate the formal economy are no more or less social than are those that animate households and love affairs. Assuming otherwise is to confuse the shadow with the shadow maker.

Notes 1. My label, conventional economics, does not mean to include economic schools of thought like institutional or Marxist economists, as they do not lie at the literal and figurative center of U.S. economic theory and practice. 2. There are a handful of instances where the focus on the “inside” of organizations included their relationship to “external” social context(s), for example, Marxist inspired organizational scholarship and critique (Braverman, 1998; Edwards, 1978, 1979; Marglin, 1974). However, this was neither mainstream

Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

1008 American Behavioral Scientist

nor common until the late 1970s and early 1980s. Marxist-inspired organizational scholarship continues to be rare indeed, as evidenced by publication dates of the above-cited research. 3. I use interpretive because it is more inclusive. The study of culture and institutions would fall under this moniker. 4. This can be observed in the endogenous citing preferences that characterize economic sociology and its overriding concern with commercial contexts and market behavior(s) (Fourcade-Gourinchas, 2005). 5. These are also referred to as heterogeneous networks.

References Abolafia, M. (1996). Making markets: Opportunism and restraint on Wall Street. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Akerlof, G. A. (1980). A theory of social custom, of which unemployment may be one consequence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 94, 749-775. Akerlof, G. A. (2001). Writing the “The market for lemons”: A personal and interpretive essay. Stockholm, Sweden: Nobel Foundation. Akerlof, G. A., & Yellen, J. L. (1985). Can small deviations from rationality make significant differences to economic equilibria? American Economic Review, 75(4), 708-720. Alexander, J. (2004). Cultural pragmatics: Social performance between ritual and strategy. Sociological Theory, 2(4), 527-573. Appelbaum, R., & Bonacich, E. (2000). Behind the label: Inequality in the Los Angeles garment industry. Berkeley: University of California Press. Baker, W. (1984). The social structure of a national securities market. American Journal of Sociology, 89, 775-811. Baker, W. E., & Faulkner, R. R. (1990). Role as resource in the Hollywood film industry. American Journal of Sociology, 97, 279-309. Baum, J. A., & Powell, W. (1995). Cultivating an institutional ecology of organizations: Comment on Hannan, Carroll, Dundon, and Torres. American Sociological Review, 60, 529-538. Beamish, T. D., & Biggart, N. W. (2005a). Economic worlds of work: Uniting economic sociology with the sociology of work. In R. H. Marek Korczynski & P. Edwards (Eds.), Social theory and work. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Beamish, T. D., & Biggart, N. W. (2005b, June 12-13). A negotiated order approach to market stability and change: The case of energy efficiency and commercial building practice. Paper presented at the European Group on Organizations, Santorini, Greece. Becker, G. S. (1976). The economic approach to human behavior. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Becker, G. S. (1996). Accounting for tastes. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Becker, G. S., & Murphy, K. M. (2000). Social economics: Market behavior in a social environment. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. Beckert, J. (2002). Beyond the market: The social foundations of economic efficiency. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Berger, P. L. (1986). The capitalist revolution. New York: Basic Books. Biggart, N. W. (1989). Charismatic capitalism: Direct selling organizations in America. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Biggart, N. W., & Beamish, T. (2003). The economic sociology of conventions: Habit, custom, practice and routine in market order. Annual Review of Sociology, 29, 443-464. Biggart, N. W., & Delbridge, R. (2004). Systems of exchange. Academy of Management Review, 29(1), 28-49. Biggart, N., & Hamilton, G. G. (1992). On the limits of firm-based theory to explain business networks. In N. Nohria and R. Eccles (Eds), Networks and organizations: Structure, form, and action (pp. 471-490). Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

Beamish / Economic Sociology in the Next Decade and Beyond 1009

Bijker, W. E. (1987). The social construction of Bakelite: Toward a theory of invention. In T. J. Pinch (Ed.), The social construction of technological systems: New directions in the sociology and history of technology (pp. x, 405). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Block, F. (1994). The roles of the state in the economy. In N. Smelser & R. Swedberg (Eds.), The handbook of economic sociology (pp. 691-710). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Block, F. (1996). The vampire state and other myths and fallacies about the U.S. economy. New York: New Press. Boltanski, L., & Chiapello, E. (1999). Le Nouvel Esprit du Capitalisme. Paris: Gallimard. Boserup, E. (1970). Women’s role in economic development. New York: St. Martin’s. Bourdieu, P. (1977). Outline of a theory of practice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Bourdieu, P. (1999). Acts of resistance: Against the tyranny of the market. New York: New Press. Bourdieu, P. (2001). Firing back against the tyranny of the market 2. New York: New Press. Bourdieu, P. (2002). Social structures of the economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Braverman, H. (1998). Labor and monopoly capital: The degradation of work in the twentieth century (25th anniversary ed.). New York: Monthly Review Press. Brecher, J., & Costello, T. (1994). Global village or global pillage: Economic reconstruction from the bottom up. Boston, MA: South End Press. Burt, R. S. (1982). Towards a structural theory of action: Network models of social structure, perceptions, and action. New York: Academic Press. Burt, R. S. (1983). Corporate profits and cooptation: Networks of market constraints and directorate ties in the American economy. New York: Academic Press. Burt, R. S. (1987). Social contagion and innovation: Cohesion versus structural equivalence. American Journal of Sociology, 92(6), 1287-1335. Burt, R. S. (1992). Structural holes: The social structure of competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Callon, M. (1992). The dynamics of techno-economic networks. In R. Coombs, P. Saviotti, & V. Walsh (Eds.), Technological change and company strategies (pp. 72-102). London: Academic Press. Callon, M. (1998). The laws of the markets. Oxford, UK/Malden, MA: Blackwell/Sociological Review. Callon, M., & Law, J. (1989). On the construction of sociotechnical networks: Content and context revisited. Knowledge and Society, 9, 57-83. Castells, M. (1992). Four Asian tigers with a dragon’s head: Comparative analsysis of state, economy, and society in the Asian Pacific Rim. In R. Appelbaum & J. Henderson (Eds), States and development in the Asian Pacific Rim. Newberry Park, CA: Sage. Catton, W. R. (1980). Overshoot, the ecological basis of revolutionary change. Urbana, IL: University of Illinois Press. Cheng, L., & Hsiung, P.-C. (1992). Women, export-oriented growth, and the state: The case of Taiwan. In R. Appelbaum & J. Henderson (Eds.), States and development in the Asian Pacific Rim. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Chong, D. (2000). Rational lives: Norms and values in politics and society. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Coleman, J. S. (1990). Foundations of social theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Coleman, J. S. (1994). A rational choice perspective on economic sociology. In N. Smelser & R. Swedberg (Eds.), The handbook of economic sociology. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Cooley, J. H. (1913). The institutional character of pecuniary valuation. American Journal of Sociology, 18, 543-555. DiMaggio, P. (1994). Culture and economy. In N. Smelser & R. Swedberg (Eds.), The handbook of economic sociology. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Dobbin, F. (1994). Forging industrial policy: The United States, Britain, and France in the railway age. New York: Cambridge University Press. Dobbin, F. (2004). The new economic sociology: A reader. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

1010 American Behavioral Scientist

Dobbin, F., & Dowd, T. J. (1997). How policy shapes competition: Early railroad foundings in Massachusetts. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42(3), 501-529. Dobbin, F., & Dowd, T. J. (2000). The market that anti-trust built. American Sociological Review, 65, 631-657. Durkheim, E. (1984). The division of labor in society (W. D. Halls, Trans.). New York: Free Press. Eatwell, J., Milgate, M., & Newman, P. (Eds.). 1987. The new Palgrave: A dictionary of economics. London: MacMillan. Edwards, R. (1978). The social relations of production at the point of production. Insurgent Sociologist, 8(2-3), 109-125. Edwards, R. (1979). Contested terrain: The transformation of the workplace in the twentieth century. New York: Basic Books. Emirbayer, M., & Goodwin, J. (1994). Network analysis, culture, and the problem of agency. American Journal of Sociology, 99(6), 1411-1454. Emirbayer, M., & Mische, A. (1998). What is agency? American Journal of Sociology, 103(4), 962-1023. Engels, F. (1902). The origin of the family, private property and the state. Chicago: C. H. Kerr & Company. Enloe, C. H. (1990). Bananas, beaches & bases: Making feminist sense of international politics (1st U.S. ed.). Berkeley: University of California Press. Escobar, A. (1995). Encountering development: The making and unmaking of the third world. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Faber, D. J. (1993). Environment under fire: Imperialism and the ecological crisis in Central America. New York: Monthly Review Press. Favereau, O. (2002). Conventions and régulation (C. Shread, Trans.). In R. Boyer & Y. Saillard (Eds.), Régulation theory: The state of the art. London: Routledge. Fine, G. A. (1984). Negotiated orders and organizational cultures. Annual Review of Sociology, 10, 239-262. Fine, G. A. (1996). Kitchens: The culture of restaurant work. Berkeley: University of California Press. Fligstein, N. (1990). The transformation of corporate control. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Fligstein, N. (1995). Networks of power or the finance conception of control? American Sociological Review, 60, 500-503. Fligstein, N. (1996). Markets as politics: A political-cultural approach to market institutions. American Sociological Review, 61, 656-673. Fligstein, N. (2001). The architecture of markets: An economic sociology of twenty-first century capitalist societies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Fligstein, N. (2002). Agreements, disagreements, and opportunities in the “new sociology of markets.” In M. F. Guillén, R. Collins, P. England, & M. Meyer (Eds.), The new economic sociology: Developments in an emerging field. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. Foster, J. B. (1999). The vulnerable planet: A short economic history of the environment. New York: Monthly Review Press. Foster, J. B. (2002). Ecology against capitalism. New York: Monthly Review Press. Fourcade-Gourinchas, M. (2005). What does the sociology of markets have to contribute to sociology? Accounts, 5(1), 3-5. Freeman, J., Carroll, G. R., & Hannan, M. T. (1983). The liability of newness: Age dependence in organizational death rates. American Sociological Review, 48(5), 692-710. Garfinkel, H. (1952). The perception of the other: A study in social order [Microform]. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University. Garfinkel, H. (1967). Studies in ethnomethodology. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall. Gereffi, G. (1989). Rethinking development theory: Insights from East Asia and Latin America. Sociological Forum, 4(4), 505-533. Gereffi, G. (1994). The organization of buyer-driven global commodity chains: How U.S. retailers shape overseas production networks. In G. Gereffi & M. Korzeniewicz (Eds.), Commmodity chains and global capitalism. Westport, CT: Praeger.

Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

Beamish / Economic Sociology in the Next Decade and Beyond 1011

Giddens, A. (1986). The constitution of society: Outline of a theory of structuration. Berkeley: University of California Press. Giddens, A. (1990). The consequences of modernity. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Goffman, E. (1959). The presentation of self in everyday life. Garden City, NY: Doubleday. Goffman, E. (1962). Interaction ritual. Garden City, NY: Doubleday. Gomez, P.-Y., & Jones, B. C. (2000). Conventions: An interpretation of deep structure in organizations. Organizational Science, 11(6), 696-708. Granovetter, M. (1985). Economic action and social structure: The problem of embeddedness. American Journal of Sociology, 91(3), 481-510. Granovetter, M. (1992). Economic institutions as social constructions: A framework for analysis. Acta Sociologica, 35, 3-11. Granovetter, M. (2002). A theoretical agenda for economic sociology. In M. F. Guillén, R. Collins, P. England, & M. Meyer (Eds.), The new economic sociology: Developments in an emerging field (pp. x, 381). New York: Russell Sage Foundation. Guillén, M. F. (2002). The new economic sociology: Developments in an emerging field. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. Hamilton, G. G. (1994). Civilization and the organization of economies. In N. Smelser & R. Swedberg (Eds.), Handbook of economic sociology (pp. 183-205). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Hamilton, G. G., & Biggart, N. (1988). Supplement: Market, culture and authority: A comparative analysis of management and organization in the Far East. American Journal of Sociology, 94, S52-S54. Hannan, M. T., & Freeman, J. (1977). The population ecology of organizations. American Journal of Sociology, 82(5), 929-964. Hargadon, A., & Douglas, Y. (2001). When innovations meet institutions: Edison and the design of the electric light. Administrative Science Quarterly, 46, 476-501. Hawken, P., Lovins, A. B., & Hunter Lovins, H. (2000). Natural capitalism: Creating the next industrial revolution. Boston: Little Brown and Co. Hayek, F. A. v. (1994). The road to serfdom (50th anniversary ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Hechter, M., & Kanazawa, S. (1997). Sociological rational choice theory. Annual Review of Sociology, 23, 191-214. Hirsch, P., Michaels, S., & Friedman, R. (1987). “Dirty hands” versus “clean models”: Is sociology in danger of being seduced by economics? Theory and Society, 16(3), 317-336. Hirshleifer, J. (1985). The expanding domain of economics. American Economic Review, 75, 53-68. Hughes, T. P. (1983). Networks of power: Electrification in Western society, 1880-1930. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Hughes, T. P., Pinch, T. J., & Bijker, W. E. (1987). The social construction of technological systems: New directions in the sociology and history of technology. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. James, W. (1908). Pragmatism: A new name for some old ways of thinking; popular lectures on philosophy. New York: Longmans, Green, and Co. Kahenman, D., Slovic, P., & Tversky, A. (1982). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Kahenman, D., & Tversky, A. (1973). On the psychology of prediction. Psychological Review, 80, 237-251. Kahenman, D., & Tversky, A. (2000). Choices, values, and frames. New York: Cambridge University Press. Kessler-Harris, A., & Levenson, R. (1982). Out to work: A history of wage-earning women in the United States. New York: Oxford University Press. Krippner, G. R. (2001). The elusive market: Embeddedness and the paradigm of economic sociology. Theory and Society, 30, 775-810. Latour, B., & Porter, C. (1996). Aramis, or, The love of technology. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Latour, B., & Woolgar, S. (1986). Laboratory life: The construction of scientific facts. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

1012 American Behavioral Scientist

Law, J., & Callon, M. (1997). The life and death of an aircraft: A network analysis of technical change. In W. E. Bijker & J. Law (Ed.), Shaping technology/building society: Studies in sociotechnical change. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Logan, J. R., and Molotch, H. L. (1987). Urban Fortunes: The political economy of place. Berkeley: University of California Press. Marglin, S. (1974). What do bosses do? The origins and functions of hierarchy in capitalist production. Review of Radical Political Economics, 6(2), 60-112. Matthaei, J. A. (1982). An economic history of women in America: Women’s work, the sexual division of labor, and the development of capitalism. New York/Brighton, UK: Schocken Books/Harvester Press. McGuire, P., & Granovetter, M. (1998). The making of an industry: Electricity in the United States. In M. Callon (Ed.), The laws of the markets. Oxford, UK: Blackwell. Mead, G. H. (2001). Essays in social psychology. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers. Menger, C. (1950). Principles of economics. First, general part. Glencoe, IL: Free Press. Meyer, J., & Rowan, B. (1977). Institutionalized organizations: Formal structure as myth and ceremony. American Journal of Sociology, 83, 340-363. Milkman, R. (1987). Gender at work: The dynamics of job segregation by sex during World War II. Urbana: University of Illinois Press. Mises, L. V. (1980). On the manipulation of money and credit. Dobbs Ferry, NY: Free Market Books. Mol, A. P. J. (1995). The refinement of production: Ecological modernization theory and the chemical industry. Utrecht: Van Arkel. Mol, A. P. J. (2001). Globalization and environmental reform: The ecological modernization of the global economy. Cambridge, MA.: MIT Press. Mol, A. P. J., Lauber, V., and Liefferink, D. (2000). The voluntary approach to environmental policy: Joint environmental policy-making in Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Mol, A. P. J., & Sonnenfeld, D. A. (Eds.). (2000). Ecological modernization around the world: Perspectives and critical debates. London: Frank Cass. Molotch, H. (1976). The city as a growth machine: toward a political economy of place. American Journal of Sociology 82, 309-332. Molotch, H. L. (1990). Sociology, economics, and the economy. In H. Gans (Ed.), Sociology in America. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. O’Connor, J. (1994). Is sustainable capitalism possible? In M. O’Connor (Ed.), Is capitalism sustainable? Political economy and the politics of ecology (pp. 152-173). New York: Guilford Press. Padgett, J., & Ansell, C. (1992). Robust action and the rise of the Medici. American Journal of Sociology, 98, 1259-1320. Parrado, E. A., & Zenteno, R. M. (2001). Economic restructuring, financial crisis, and women’s work in Mexico. Social Problems, 48(4), 456-477. Parsons, T., & Smelser, N. J. (1956). Economy and society: A study in the integration of economic and social theory. Glencoe, IL: Free Press. Pellow, D. N., Schnaiberg, A, & Weinberg, A. S. (2000). Putting the ecological modernization thesis to the test: The promise and performance of urban recycling. In A. P. J. Mol and D. A. Sonnenfeld, (Eds), Ecological modernization around the world: Perspectives and critical debates (pp. 109-137). London: Frank Cass. Perrow, C. (1972). The radical attack on business. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich. Perrow, C. (2002). Organizing America: Wealth, power, and the origins of corporate capitalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Pfeffer, J., & Salancik, G. R. (1978). The external control of organizations: A resource dependence perspective. New York: Harper & Row. Pinch, T. J. 2003. Emulating sound—What synthesizers can and can’t do: Explorations in the social construction of sound. Paper presented at the IV annual Cultural Turn Conference, University of California, Santa Barbara. Ithaca, NY: Department of Science and Technology Studies, Cornell University.

Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

Beamish / Economic Sociology in the Next Decade and Beyond 1013

Podolny, J. M. (1993). A status based model market competition. American Journal of Sociology, 98, 829-872. Podolny, J. M. (1994). Market uncertainty and the social character of economic exchange. Administrative Science Quarterly, 39(3), 458. Polanyi, K. (1947). Our obsolete market mentality: Civilization must find a new thought pattern. Commentary, 3(2), 109-117. Polanyi, K. (1957a). The economy as instituted process. In K. Polanyi, Conrad M. Arensberg, & Harry W. Pearson (Eds.), Trade and market in the early empires: Economies in history and theory. Glencoe, IL: Free Press. Polanyi, K. (1957b). The great transformation. Boston: Beacon. Popkin, S. L. (1979). The rational peasant: The political economy of rural society in Vietnam. Berkeley: University of California Press. Postrel, V. (2005, July 24). Market share: Economists have long used their tools to analyze social phenomena. Now sociologists are learning to stop worrying and love—or at least study—the market. Boston Globe. Powell, W. W. (1998). Learning from collaboration: Knowledge and networks in the biotechnology and pharmaceutical industries. California Management Review, 40(3), 228-240. Ridgeway, C. L. (1997). Interaction and the conservation of gender inequality: Considering employment. American Sociological Review, 62(2), 218-235. Schelling, T. C. (1960). The strategy of conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Schnaiberg, A. (1980). The environment, from surplus to scarcity. New York: Oxford University Press. Schnaiberg, A, & Gould, K. A. (2000). Environment and society: The enduring conflict. Caldwell, NJ: Blackburn Press. Schumpeter, J. (1934). The theory of economic development (R. Opie, Trans.) (2nd ed.). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Sewell, W. H. J. (1992). A theory of structure: Duality, agency, and transformation. American Journal of Sociology, 98(1), 1-29. Smelser, N. J., & Swedberg, R. (1994). The handbook of economic sociology. Princeton, NJ/New York: Princeton University Press/Russell Sage Foundation. Smith, C. W. (1989). Auctions: The social construction of value. New York: Free Press. Spaargaren, G, Mol, A. P. J., & Buttel, F. H. (2000). Environment and global modernity. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications. Spillman, L. (1999). Enriching exchange: Cultural dimensions of markets. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 58(4), 1047-1072. Stiglitz, J. E. (1999). Reforming the global economic architecture: Lessons from recent crises. Journal of Finance, 54(4), 1508-1521. Stiglitz, J. E. (2002). Globalization and its discontents. New York: Norton. Strauss, A. L. (1978). Negotiations: Varieties, contexts, processes, and social order. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. Swaminathan, A., & Carroll, G. R. (2000). Why the microbrewery movement? Organizational dynamics of resource partitioning in the American brewing industry after prohibition. American Journal of Sociology, 106, 715-762. Swedberg, R. (1987). Economic sociology: Past and present. Current Sociology, 35(1), 1-221. Thévenot, L. (1994, July). An approach to the economics of conventions: The plurality of modes of coordination. Paris: Ecole des Hautes Etudes en Sciences Sociales et Centre d’Etudes de l’Emploi. Thévenot, L. (1998, April 23-25). Innovating in “qualified” markets: Quality, norms and conventions. Paper presented at the Systems and Trajectories of Agricultural Innovation, University of California, Berkeley. Treiman, D. J., & Roos, P. A. (1983). Sex and earnings in industrial society: A nine-nation comparison. American Journal of Sociology, 89(3), 612-650.

Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.

1014 American Behavioral Scientist

Uzzi, B. (1996). The sources and consequences of embeddedness for the economic performance of organizations: The network effect. American Sociological Review, 61, 674-698. Uzzi, B. (1999). Embeddedness in the making of financial capital: How social relations and networks benefit firms seeking financing. American Sociological Review, 64(4), 674-505. Weber, M. (1922/1968). Economy and society: An outline of interpretive sociology (E. Fischoff, Trans.). New York: Bedminster Press. White, H. (1981). Where do markets come from? American Journal of Sociology, 87(3), 517-547. White, H. (2002). Markets from networks. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Wilkinson, J. (1997). A new paradigm for economic analysis? Economy and Society, 26, 305-339. Williamson, O. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. New York: Free Press. Williamson, O. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press. Winner, L. (1987). Autonomous technology: Technics out of control as a theme in political thought (6th ed.). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Wrong, D. (1961). The oversocialized conception of man in modern sociology. American Journal of Sociology, 26, 183-196. York, R., Rosa, E., & Dietz, T. (2003). Footprints on the earth: The environmental consequences of modernity. American Sociological Review, 60, 279-300. Zelizer, V. (1979). Morals and markets: The development of life insurance in the United States. New York: Columbia University Press. Zelizer, V. (1988). Beyond the polemics of the market: Establishing a theoretical and empirical agenda. Sociological Forum, 3, 614-634. Zelizer, V. A. (1994). Pricing the priceless child: The changing social value of children. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Zelizer, V. (2002). Enter culture. In M. F. Guillén, R. Collins, P. England, & M. Meyer (Eds.), The new economic sociology: Developments in an emerging field (pp. x, 381). New York: Russell Sage Foundation. Zelizer, V. A. (2005a). Circuits of capitalism. In V. Nee & R. Swedberg (Eds), The economic sociology of capitalism (pp. 289-322). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Zelizer, V. A. (2005b). The purchase of intimacy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Zukin, S., & DiMaggio, P. (1990). Structures of capital: The social organization of the economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Thomas D. Beamish is an associate professor of sociology at the University of California, Davis. His research interests include organizations, institutions, and economy; environment and technology; and hazards research. Each of these interests, in turn, reflects his deeper substantive focus on the structuring influence that social institutions and complex/formal/informal organization exerts on interpretation and practice. Through field work in a diverse range of settings—oil fields and the oil industry; commercial construction markets; antiwar protest; and a current NSF-funded study of community response to a federally sponsored biodefense initiative—his research has sought to illuminate the part social expectations play in configuring the intentional rationality of human actors. His publications include a book, Silent Spill: The Organization of an Industrial Crisis (MIT Press, 2002); chapters in edited volumes; and professional journal articles that have appeared in the Journal of Social Problems, the Annual Review of Sociology, and Organization and Environment among others.

Downloaded from http://abs.sagepub.com at UNIV CALIFORNIA DAVIS on April 6, 2007 © 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution.