THE PRICING OF QUANTO OPTIONS IN THE ... - MathNet Korea

0 downloads 0 Views 129KB Size Report
quanto call option in the double square root stochastic volatility model. 1. ... Cox-Ingersoll-Ross process, F. A. Longstaff [5] introduced a double square root.
Commun. Korean Math. Soc. 29 (2014), No. 3, pp. 489–496 http://dx.doi.org/10.4134/CKMS.2014.29.3.489

THE PRICING OF QUANTO OPTIONS IN THE DOUBLE SQUARE ROOT STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY MODEL Youngrok Lee and Jaesung Lee Abstract. We drive a closed-form expression for the price of a European quanto call option in the double square root stochastic volatility model.

1. Introduction A quanto is a type of financial derivative whose pay-out currency differs from the natural denomination of its underlying financial variable, which allows that investors are to obtain exposure to foreign assets without the corresponding foreign exchange risk. A quanto option has both the strike price and the underlying asset price denominated in foreign currency. At exercise, the value of the option is calculated as the option’s intrinsic value in the foreign currency, which is then converted to the domestic currency at the fixed exchange rate. Pricing options based on the classical Black-Scholes model, on which most of the research on quanto options has focused, has a problem of assuming a constant volatility which leads to smiles and skews in the implied volatility of the underlying asset. For that reason, in valuing quanto option, it is natural to consider a stochastic volatility model. Stochastic volatility models, such as Hull-White model [4], Stein-Stein model [8] and Heston model [3], are frequently used in pricing various kinds of European options. Despite its importance, very few researches have been done on pricing quanto option using a stochastic volatility model primarily due to the sophisticated stochastic process for underlying assets and volatilities as well as the difficulty of finding analytic form of the option price. To mention some of the work on pricing quanto options with stochastic volatilities, F. Antonelli et al. [1] used a method of expanding and approximating with respect to correlation parameters to find analytic formula of exchange options with stochastic volatilities. Using the technique developed in [1], J. Park et al. [6] got an analytic approximation value for a quanto option price in the Hull-White stochastic volatility model. A. Giese [2] provided a closed-form Received April 14, 2014; Revised May 19, 2014. 2010 Mathematics Subject Classification. Primary 91B25, 91G60, 65C20. Key words and phrases. quanto option, quanto measure, stochastic volatility, double square root model, closed-form expression. c

2014 Korean Mathematical Society

489

490

Y. LEE AND J. LEE

expression for the price of quanto option in the Stein-Stein stochastic volatility model, which was influenced by the previous work of R. Sch¨ obel and J. Zhu [7]. On the other hand, extending to a general equilibrium framework of the Cox-Ingersoll-Ross process, F. A. Longstaff [5] introduced a double square root model of stochastic interest rates to describe nonlinear term structures observed in yield curves. Later, J. Zhu [9], [10] presented an innovative modification of stochastic volatility models specified as a double square root stochastic process with the restriction of parameters. In this paper, motivated by A. Giese [2] and J. Zhu [10], we drive a closedform expression for the price of a quanto call option in the double square root stochastic volatility model. Here, we use the double square root stochastic process with the restriction of parameters introduced in [10] to get the main theorem. We introduce preliminary materials on a quanto and the double square root stochastic volatility model, and specify dynamics of the processes of underlying asset and its volatility under the quanto measure in Section 2. Then, in Section 3, we drive a closed-form expression of a quanto option price under the model specified in Section 2. Theorem 3.3 is the main result of the paper. 2. Model specification For a non-dividend paying asset, the process of the asset price St may be assumed to be denominated in foreign currency X and to have the following dynamics: (1) (2)

X √ dSt = rX St dt + vt St dBtQ , X √ √ dvt = κ (θ − vt ) dt + ξ vt dWtQ X

X

under the risk-neutral probability measure QX , where BtQ and WtQ are two standard Brownian motions, rX is the foreign riskless rate and vt follows the stochastic volatility process of St with constant parameters κ, θ and ξ. Since there are two square root terms in (2), it is referred to as the double square root process, whose basic features are described in Chapter 3.4 of [10]. To give a closed-form expression, we should add a restriction of parameters so that 4κθ = ξ 2 , which is the strong condition to be able to analytically calculate some special conditional expectation included vt . This particular meaning is explained in [5] minutely. Furthermore, we assume an investor whose domestic currency is Y and who wishes to obtain exposure to the asset price St without carrying the corresponding foreign exchange risk. For the rest of Section 2, we mostly follow the notations of [2]. Y /X Let Zt denote the price of one unit of currency Y in units of currency X Y /X and we assume that Zt follows the standard Black-Scholes type dynamics

THE PRICING OF QUANTO OPTIONS IN THE DSR SV MODEL

491

under QX such as Y /X

dZt X

 Y /X ˆ QX = rX − rY Zt Y /X dt + σZt dBt ,

ˆ Q is a standard Brownian motion under QX , rY is the domestic where B t riskless rate and σ is the constant volatility of the foreign exchange rate Zt . This model allows three constant correlations ρ, ν and β satisfying X

X

dBtQ dWtQ = ρdt,

X

X

ˆtQ = νdt, dBtQ dB

X

X

ˆtQ = βdt. dWtQ dB

Using the change of measure from QX to the domestic risk-neutral probability measure QY with the Radon-Nikod´ ym derivative Y /X X Zt dQY (rY −rX )t = e− 12 σ2 t+σ BˆtQ , = e Y /X dQX Ft Z0 Y

Y

the Girsanov’s Theorem implies that the processes BtQ , WtQ fined by Y

Y

ˆtQ and B

de-

X

dBtQ = dBtQ − νσdt, Y

X

dWtQ = dWtQ − βσdt, Y

X

ˆ Q + σdt ˆ Q = dB dB t t

are again standard Brownian motions under the domestic risk-neutral probability measure QY , so called the quanto measure. Thus, the foreign exchange X/Y rate Zt denoting the price in currency X per unit of the domestic currency Y follows  X/Y X/Y ˆ QY = rY − rX Zt X/Y dt + σZt dBt . dZt

Also, we obtain the following dynamics of St and vt under QY : Y √ √  dSt = rX + νσ vt St dt + vt St dBtQ , (3)  Y √ √  (4) dvt = κ ˆ θˆ − vt dt + ξ vt dWtQ

κθ with κ ˆ = κ − βσξ and θˆ = κ−βσξ . We notice that (4) maintains the same form 2 ˆ as (2) so that 4ˆ κθ = ξ also has to be satisfied.

3. A closed-form quanto option price Here, using the model specified in previous section, we drive a closed-form expression of a quanto option price. The following two lemmas are about some special conditional expectations under the measure QY , both of which are crucial ingredients to the main result of the paper.

492

Y. LEE AND J. LEE

Lemma 3.1. Under the assumption of (4), together with constants m1 , m2 and m3 , we get the following equality: i h RT √ √ EQY e− t (m1 vs +m2 vs )ds+m3 vT Ft = A (t) eB(t)vt +C(t) vt , where

1 A (t) = √ exp γ4

"

    γ2 γ3 − 2ˆ κγ12 γ3 1 γ32 − κ ˆ 2 γ12 (T − t) + − 1 2ξ 2 γ12 2ξ 2 γ14 γ4  2    1 γ2 γ3 2 2 2 sinh {γ1 (T − t)} κ ˆ γ1 − κ ˆ γ2 γ3 − γ3 + 2 γ 1  , + 3  2 2ξ γ1 γ4

B (t) = − and 2 sinh C (t) =

n

2γ1 2γ1 sinh {γ1 (T − t)} + γ2 cosh {γ1 (T − t)} · ξ 2 2γ1 cosh {γ1 (T − t)} + γ2 sinh {γ1 (T − t)}

γ1 (T −t) 2

o

ξ 2 γ1 γ4        γ1 (T −t) γ2 γ3 γ1 (T −t) × (ˆ κγ2 − 2γ3 ) cosh + 2ˆ κγ1 − sinh 2 γ1 2

with p 2m1 ξ 2 γ1 = , 2

γ2 = −m3 ξ 2 ,

γ4 = cosh {γ1 (T − t)} +

γ3 =

m2 ξ 2 , 2

γ2 sinh {γ1 (T − t)}. 2γ1

Proof. Let us define i h RT √ y (t, vt ) = EQY e− t (m1 vs +m2 vs )ds+m3 vT Ft .

Then according to the Feynman-Kaˇc formula, y is the solution of the following PDE:  √  √  ∂y ξ2 ∂ 2 y ∂y ˆ θˆ − v v 2 +κ − m1 v + m2 v y + =0 2 ∂v ∂v ∂t with the terminal condition y (T, vT ) = em3 vT . Now, putting our solution as the following functional form: y (t, vt ) = A (t) eB(t)vt +C(t)



vt

,

THE PRICING OF QUANTO OPTIONS IN THE DSR SV MODEL

493

we have the following ODEs1: ξ2 ξ2 κ ˆ 2 A (t) C (t) − A (t) B (t) + A (t) C (t) , 8 4 2 ξ2 2 ′ B (t) = − B (t) + m1 , 2 2 ξ ˆ B (t) + m2 C ′ (t) = − B (t) C (t) + κ 2 with terminal conditions A′ (t) = −

A (T ) = 1,

B (T ) = m3 ,

C (T ) = 0.

By solving these ODEs, we complete the proof of the lemma.



Using the result obtained in Lemma 3.1, we can compute EQY [ ST | Ft ] which represents, from the risk-neutral valuation, the value of a quanto forward contract. Lemma 3.2. Under the assumptions of (3) and (4), we get the following equality: i h RT √ ρ X ˆ EQY [ ST | Ft ] = St er (T −t)− ξ {vt +ˆκθ(T −t)} EQY e− t (c1 vs +c2 vs )ds+c3 vT Ft ,

where c1 , c2 and c3 are constants with ρ2 , 2

c1 =

c2 = −νσ −

ρˆ κ , ξ

c3 =

ρ . ξ

Proof. Applying the Itˆ o formula to (3) together with the tower property, we get (5)   RT √ RT √ ρ2 R T QY X EQY [ ST | Ft ] = St er (T −t) EQY eνσ t vs ds− 2 t vs ds+ρ t vs dWs Ft , Y

where we may write BtQ

Y

as BtQ

Y

= ρWtQ +

p 1 − ρ2 Wt with Wt being a Y

QY -standard Brownian motion independent of WtQ . From (4), we have ) ( Z T Z T √ √ 1 QY ˆ (6) vT − vt − κ ˆ θ (T − t) + κ ˆ vs dWs = vs ds . ξ t t Substituting (6) into (5), we obtain EQY [ ST | Ft ] = St er

X

ˆ −t)} (T −t)− ρ κθ(T ξ {vt +ˆ

with c1 =

ρ2 , 2

i h RT √ EQY e− t (c1 vs +c2 vs )ds+c3 vT Ft

c2 = −νσ −

ρˆ κ , ξ

c3 =

ρ . ξ



1Due to the restriction that 4ˆ κθˆ = ξ 2 , the coefficient of v1 vanishes in the calculating t

course.

494

Y. LEE AND J. LEE

Using the results obtained in Lemma 3.1 and Lemma 3.2, we can obtain a closed-form expression of the quanto option price. Here is the main theorem. Theorem 3.3. Let us denote the log-asset price by xt = ln St . Under the assumptions of (3) and (4), the price of a European quanto call option in currency Y with strike price K and maturity T is given by cq (t, St ) = EQY [ ST | Ft ] e−r

Y

(T −t)

where P1 , P2 are defined by

1 1 + 2 π

Pj =

Z



Re

0



P1 − Ke−r

Y

(T −t)

P2 ,

 eiφ ln K fj (φ) dφ iφ

for j = 1, 2, in which ρ X ˆ i h RT √ e(1+iφ)[r (T −t)+xt − ξ {vt +ˆκθ(T −t)}] EQY e− t (m1 vs +m2 vs )ds+m3 vT Ft f1 (φ) = EQY [ ST | Ft ]

with

m1 =

ρ2 (1 + iφ) , 2

and f2 (φ) = with

eiφ[r

X

  ρˆ κ , m2 = − (1 + iφ) νσ + ξ

ˆ −t)}] κθ(T (T −t)+xt − ρ ξ {vt +ˆ

EQY [ ST | Ft ] n1 = iφ

ρ2 , 2

m3 =

ρ (1 + iφ) ξ

i h RT √ EQY e− t (n1 vs +n2 vs )ds+n3 vT Ft

  ρˆ κ , n2 = −iφ νσ + ξ

ρ n3 = iφ . ξ

Proof. From the risk-neutral valuation, the price cq (t, St ) of a European quanto call option in currency Y with strike price K and maturity T is given by cq (t, St ) = e−r

Y

(T −t)

EQY [ max (ST − K, 0)| Ft ] .

˜ Y , the Radon-Nikod´ For a new risk-neutral probability measure Q ym derivative Y Y ˜ with respect to Q is defined by of Q ˜Y ST dQ = . Y dQ EQY [ ST | Ft ]

Thus, the price of a quanto call option can be rewritten as   Y cq (t, St ) = e−r (T −t) EQY ST 1{ST >K} − K1{ST >K} Ft = EQY [ ST | Ft ] e−r

= EQY [ ST | Ft ] e−r

Y

(T −t)

Y

(T −t)

˜ Y (ST > K) − Ke−rY (T −t) QY (ST > K) Q P1 − Ke−r

Y

(T −t)

P2

with the risk-neutralized probabilities P1 and P2 . Now, putting xt = ln St , the corresponding characteristic functions f1 and f2 can be represented as   f1 (φ) = E ˜ Y eiφxT Ft Q

THE PRICING OF QUANTO OPTIONS IN THE DSR SV MODEL

495

i h 1 EQY e(1+iφ)xT Ft , EQY [ ST | Ft ]   f2 (φ) = EQY eiφxT Ft . =

On the other hand, applying the Itˆ o formula to (3), we have   p Y √ √ √ 1 dxt = rX + νσ vt − vt dt + ρ vt dWtQ + 1 − ρ2 vt dWt . 2

From (6), we obtain f1 (φ) =

e(1+iφ)[r

ˆ −t)}] (T −t)+xt − ρ κθ(T ξ {vt +ˆ

EQY [ ST | Ft ]

with m1 =

X

ρ2 (1 + iφ) , 2

Similarly, we also obtain f2 (φ) = with

eiφ[r

X

i h RT √ EQY e− t (m1 vs +m2 vs )ds+m3 vT Ft

  ρˆ κ , m2 = − (1 + iφ) νσ + ξ

ˆ −t)}] κθ(T (T −t)+xt − ρ ξ {vt +ˆ

EQY [ ST | Ft ]

m3 =

ρ (1 + iφ) . ξ

i h RT √ EQY e− t (n1 vs +n2 vs )ds+n3 vT Ft

  ρ2 ρ ρˆ κ , n3 = iφ . , n2 = −iφ νσ + 2 ξ ξ Here, each value of risk-neutral expectation above was obtained in previous Lemmas. By having closed-form solutions for the characteristic functions f1 and f2 , the Fourier inversion formula allows us to compute the probabilities P1 and P2 as follows:   iφ ln K Z 1 ∞ e fj (φ) 1 dφ Re Pj = + 2 π 0 iφ for j = 1, 2.  n1 = iφ

Acknowledgement. The authors want to express their gratitude to the anonymous referee for helpful comments. References [1] F. Antonelli, A. Ramponi, and S. Scarlatti, Exchange option pricing under stochastic volatility: a correlation expansion, Rev. Deriv. Res. 13 (2010), no. 1, 45–73. [2] A. Giese, Quanto adjustments in the presence of stochastic volatility, Risk Magazine, Mar 14, 2012. [3] S. L. Heston, A closed-form solution for options with stochastic volatility with applications to bond and currency options, Rev. Financ. Stud. 6 (1993), no. 2, 327–343. [4] J. Hull and A. White, The pricing of options on assets with stochastic volatilities, J. Finance 42 (1987), no. 2, 281–300. [5] F. A. Longstaff, A nonlinear general equilibrium model of the term structure of interest rates, J. Financ. Econ. 23 (1989), 195–224.

496

Y. LEE AND J. LEE

[6] J. Park, Y. Lee, and J. Lee, Pricing of quanto option under the Hull and White stochastic volatility model, Commun. Korean Math. Soc. 28 (2013), no. 3, 615–633 [7] R. Sch¨ obel and J. Zhu, Stochastic volatility with an Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process: an extension, Europ. Finance Rev. 3 (1999), 23–46. [8] E. M. Stein and J. C. Stein, Stock price distributions with stochastic volatility: an analytic approach, Rev. Financ. Stud. 4 (1991), no. 4, 727–752. [9] J. Zhu, Modular Pricing of Options, Springer, Berlin, 2000. [10] , Applications of Fourier Transform to Smile Modeling, 2nd ed., Springer, Berlin, 2010. Youngrok Lee Department of Mathematics Sogang University Seoul 121-742, Korea E-mail address: [email protected] Jaesung Lee Department of Mathematics Sogang University Seoul 121-742, Korea E-mail address: [email protected]