the Silk Road - European International Studies Association

2 downloads 133 Views 421KB Size Report
However, it is significant that “Chinese junks still sailed to Malacca, to ..... maritime power of the north Sumatran Sultanate in Acheh, they failed to prevent a.
Dancing spatialities around a geopolitical continuity: the Silk Road Igor Filibi1 1. Introduction The theories of Braudel and Wallerstein are well known, and even more so in this specialist forum, as are their key concepts of world-economy, world-system and the structuring power of core - periphery relations. For this reason, rather than outlining these concepts yet again, I consider it to be more appropriate to point out the principal problems facing these theories. Firstly, Eurocentrism, which constantly appears, however much one would like to transcend it, and even the world-system notion put forward by Wallerstein (1976) is affected by this bias (Dussel 2002:222-224). For this reason, the study of the Silk Road and the centrality held for a long time by Asia, carries the advantage that the very nature of the subject matter of the study tends to reduce this habitual problem. Secondly, even accepting the explanatory power of the concepts of world-economy and world-system, there are some points that are still not clear, specifically: a) when did a single worldeconomy emerge from the former plurality? Some authors set the date in the 15th - 16th centuries (Wallerstein and, with some qualifications, Braudel as well), whilst others (Frank/Gills 1993; Frank 1998) go back many centuries earlier, suggesting 5000 years of antiquity instead of just 500; and b) when did a world-system actually come into being? Although, on this point, there is less debate, with the mid-18th century being the generally accepted date (Wallerstein). Thirdly, these approaches revolve around the historical emergence and development of capitalism. However, given the fact that this is a problematical concept (what is capitalism? when can a society to be considered to be capitalist? who were the first capitalists?) some authors such as Frank openly criticise it, whilst others such as Hamashita prefer to avoid it directly (Arrighi 2003:133). In any case, it seems erroneous to place the historical origins of capitalism in 16 th century Italy, given the fact that, whatever criterion is used to define capitalism, these conditions appear to have already been met in 11th century northern Italy or in some of the commercial cities of Asia, such as Samarkand, Bukhara, etc. many centuries ago. Perhaps it would be a good idea not to 1

University of the Basque Country, [email protected]

centre so much on the concept of capitalism and to focus instead on describing and understanding the trading and banking practices, the development of the routes and the geographical and geopolitical conditioning factors forming the framework for these routes over the centuries. Fourthly, despite the notable attempts to transcend the "territorial trap", almost all studies are to a great extent state-centred (Agnew 1994). In this respect, the innovative work by geographers over the last decades has been of great help in going some way towards achieving this, although much work still remains to be done. Related to this, fifthly, despite the "shift" towards geography, problems are still being experienced with regard to the way in which space is understood or denied, given the fact that in the majority of texts, space continues to be an ahistorical category that is understood to be a “container” (Brenner 1999:41). Finally, without providing a complete, in-depth study, I would like to mention the problem of sources, which give almost absolute priority to historiographical studies, and completely leave out the numerous and highly stimulating recent progress in archaeology (Wilkinson, Petrie, Larsen, Marfoe, Sherratt, etc.). This implies biases in period dating which, as shall be seen, can become extremely serious (Christian 2000). With all their problems, in my opinion, the theoretical approaches of Braudel, Wallerstein, Frank, Agnew, O‟Tuathail, etc., constitute the best starting point for an analysis of present day society, being some of the few approaches which base their analysis on the world as a whole, integrating the historical dimension and also incorporating matters of inequality and power relations. In this paper, we would suggest the possibility of adding to this framework, the concept of space based on the notions of Henri Lefebvre, and we would put forward the need to refine the mentioned theories based on empirical studies, suggesting the concept of Space / network. With this aim in mind, we have selected the case of the so-called Silk Road, to offer an example of continuity over many centuries and with an almost global geographical coverage. To now focus on the actual Silk Road, although this name was coined in the 19th century by a European, the network of routes linking Far East Asia with Europe and Africa is extremely old and stretches far back over time. It is sufficient to look at a physical map of Asia, to get an idea of the magnitude and difficulty of the journey between the East and West (map 1).

The route starts out from the former imperial city of Chang‟an (present day Xi‟an), to go up-river up to Lanzhou, on the banks of the river Huang He. It then continues northwest along the fertile corridor of the Hexe (Wuwei, Zhangye, Jiayuguan) to the Gobi desert. There, at the city of Anxi, the road forks either to the north (Turfan) or to the south (Khotan) to border the terrible Takla Makan desert, one of the most arid deserts on the planet. Both branches merge once again at Kashgar to cross the glaciercovered Pamir mountain chain, which is only passable in summer. On the other side lies the Fergana basin, going on to Samarkand and Bukhara, located between the rivers SyrDaria and Amu-Daria (Sogdiana). The route then continues amidst impressive deserts (Kizikum, Karakum), passing through the city of Merv, to border the Caspian Sea to the south, from one oasis to another, crossing the Zagros Mountains at Hamadan to reach Bagdad. From there the route runs upwards, parallel to the river Euphrates and crosses the Syrian desert to reach Palmyra, Damascus or Aleppo, it then crosses the mountain chains running parallel to the coast to reach the Mediterranean ports: Antioquia or Tiro (Höllmann 2008:28-30).

Map 1. The Silk Road

Source: Höllmann 2008:10-11

Chinese researchers have stressed that there was also another silk road to the south, which started in south-west China, passed through Sichuan and Yunan and crossed Burma to reach India. This trade route (2008:31-2) was already operating by at least 400 BC and carried considerable importance (Ma 1998). In addition to this south-western route, Höllmann indicates the existence of other branches and also other routes established for specific products, such as the routes for amber, incense or jade (2008:312). Likewise, mention should also be made of the maritime route connecting the south of China with the Indian Ocean, which crossed the Persian Gulf or the Red Sea, to reach the Mediterranean (Höllmann 2008:32-37), and which emerged almost at the same time as the land route (Ma 1998). Although the traditional version places the commencement of the Silk Road at around the 1st century BC, a number of authors have suggested that this trade was probably much older. It is customary to consider the Silk Route to be no more than the unification of former regional routes, in particular the union of the western route of Lapis Lazuli (connecting the Chagai mountains with Mesopotamia) with the western jade route supplying China through Sinkiang (Sherratt 2004). For this reason, it appears appropriate to start our research by considering the ancient routes which were to be the prelude to the much longer, better prepared and more regular Silk Road.

2. The ancient routes: a prelude to the Silk Road

Mesopotamia, the land lying between the Tigris and Euphrates rivers, witnessed an agricultural revolution around 10000 BC, whilst the first urban civilization developed there around 3500 BC (Ur). The Egyptian civilization was the next to coalesce, with the unification of the upper and lower Nile around 3150 BC, whilst, around 2500 BC, a third civilization emerged in the Indus valley. Despite their differences, these three urban civilizations do have some points in common with regard to technology and various aspects of their culture, leading historians to assume some type of intercommunication in their early stages of development, contrary to the other great Asian civilization: China, whose development was more independent (Curtin 1998:60). Therefore, a constitutive feature of the development of these civilisations was the long

distance trade between Mesopotamia, Egypt and the Indus valley, in addition to the associated technological and cultural exchanges. Map 2 shows how the natural barrier formed by the Himalaya and Hindu Kush mountain ranges complicated communications between China and the Indus valley. It also shows the communications by sea between this region and the Persian Gulf, into which the great rivers of Mesopotamia flow, to then follow the course of the river Euphrates and cross the Syrian desert to reach northern Egypt.

Map 2 – Early civilizations and their relations

Source: Igor Filibi

The civilization of Mesopotamia stretched along the banks of the Tigris and Euphrates rivers, with their routes connecting the Persian Gulf with the Mediterranean Sea. In actual fact, maritime trade in the Persian Gulf (which is age-old, dating back to the late sixth millennium BC) preceded the appearance of the complex state societies (Carter 2006:61). These maritime routes and their systems of exchange, particularly the supply of grain and copper, gradually evolved into a political economy in the entire area, configuring a number of cores and peripheries, which were superimposed with political, military and cultural cores and peripheries, which in turn created the context for trade (Edens 1992). The contacts through the Persian Gulf were so intense that some archaeologists have suggested that "the trade links by land and sea could have been the cause of the civilization in the Indus valley, and not just the result” (Curtin 1998:66).

Also, right from the start, there were contacts and exchanges between Mesopotamia and the Levant in the Mediterranean and Anatolia. King Sargon (2300 BC) unified the territories lying between the coasts of these two seas into a single empire. This initial moment of unification no doubt strengthened the trade and cultural links and served to integrate the territory still further. The shortage of metals in Mesopotamia proved a constant stimulus for seeking new sources and commerce. Copper was brought in through the Persian Gulf from Oman and beyond, and, from the north, different metals came from the Caucasus, Anatolia (gold and silver) and the Iranian plateau (tin). After the fall of the Sargon dynasty and a brief period of instability, a new political entity emerged around the city of Babylon, with profound legal changes, such as those introduced by Hammurabi, and also economic changes, since the temples were no longer the centre of economic commercial activity, the royal monopolies practically disappeared and the Tamkaru, an independent class of merchants came to dominate trade, brokerage and money lending. The government continued to maintain a certain control and to charge taxes, but the majority of trade became a private activity (Curtin 1998:66-68). Map 3 – Ancient and Middle Egyptian Empire

Source: http://es.wikipedia.org

In the same way as trade between Mesopotamia and the Indus valley was key to the development of this civilisation, the unification of Egypt must be associated with the trade contacts between the Nile delta and the route connecting Syria with Mesopotamia and Anatolia (map 3). In fact, the boom in this trade occurred simultaneously with the unification of the Egyptian State (3000 BC) within the framework of the wars of conquest between the three proto-kingdoms of Upper Egypt (Nagada, Hierakonpolis and Abydos) "for the control of the exchange routes for prestigious goods" (Campagno cited by Flammini 2005:15). Likewise, it is considered that the monopoly of this lucrative trade (copper in particular) undoubtedly contributed to the centralisation of the State (Marfoe 1987;26). Although few details are known, during the Middle Empire (2050 - 1750 BC) a number of Egyptian settlements were established in the Syrian Palestinian area and diplomatic contacts with representatives of peoples in Asia revealed the frequency and intensity of some pacific and principally commercial relations with Asia (González-Tablas 2010:245). In this way, a complex network of overland trade routes was gradually constructed and which, at the beginning of the second millennium BC, linked areas as different as Afghanistan, the vast plateaux of Iran, Mesopotamia, the plains of Syria and Anatolia (Larsen 1987:47). To this system, the maritime trading routes should be added, which, despite all the dangers involved, linked the Red Sea, the Persian Gulf, and the west coast of India (Carter 2001, 2003). The routes also crossed the Sahara desert, in a north - south direction and east to west, following the paths of the oases. Caravans transporting gold from Ghana, Senegal and Mauritania to the north in exchange for essential salt (Sanz Roche 2001). In turn, communications were established between the great trading centres such as Timbuktu and Agadez with the Nile delta. Following the river course, gold from Nubia (present day Sudan) and other products from this contemporary Egyptian civilisation also reached the Nile delta (Gonzalez-Tablas 2010:240-1). The pharaohs soon sent trading expeditions to the horn of Africa, where, in the land of Punt, they had access to the tropical products of sub-Saharan Africa. (Phillips 1997).2

2

The route between Egypt and Punt Land passed through the Red Sea after crossing the desert. The first expedition, of which there are details, took place at the initiative of queen Hatshepsut (1473 - 1458 BC), but there is already evidence of the arrival of products from Punt in the period of the fifty dynasty. An

Obligatory transit centres such as oases, mountain passes, caravan crossroads, or sheltered ports, gave rise to cities which started to make their livelihood from trade rather than what they produced. In this way, cities arose without an agricultural hinterland to support them, and therefore also depend on commerce for their subsistence, as illustrated by the exemplary case of Assur (Bauer 1998:160; Larsen 1987:53). In this way, a network of cities was created which, due to their capacity to control and exploit the routes passing through them, were to condition the rise and fall of empires for many centuries to come.

The central area of the Near East, from the Zagros mountains to the Mediterranean and from the Persian Gulf to the Tauro mountains and, at times, extending as far as the Black Sea, appears to have formed a natural unit, since few goods needed to be introduced from outside and there was a highly developed network of routes and exchanges within the region, undoubtedly connected to Egypt. This region had a number of centres which did not compete politically amongst themselves, although there were conflicts within each region (Mesopotamia in the south, Anatolia, Syria) but which did not affect the interregional trade, regulated by written treaties (Larsen 1987:53). In turn, the Egyptian empire gradually integrated the territory in Upper and Lower Egypt into a single commercial and economic network which stretched towards the south and towards the west through the desert. Neither did it abandon control of the north-eastern trade, and to ensure its safety, by establishing military posts at strategic places such as Ugarit, Byblos, Gaza, Jerusalem etc. and with the presence of its fleet. For this reason, between the 16th and 14th centuries BC, the contact zone for these great centres (Mitanni, Egypt, Hattie), namely the Syrian - Palestinian corridor, became a "disputed periphery", being the place where the Near Eastern routes converged and the location of the ports for the exchange of goods with the Eastern Mediterranean (Gestoso 2006:16). Despite the geo-political tension between the powers over the control of these routes, there was always a shared limit to this tension, due to the need to maintain trade. For this same reason, in the majority of cases, the empires were content to set up a few garrisons to protect their

inscription in the reign of Sahure (2458 - 2446 BC) details the importation of a number of products from Punt, including myrrh (Phillips 1997:426).

interests and solely had recourse to physical control when the conflicts between the local powers endangered the route (Gestoso 2006:16). In this way, for most of the Bronze Age, the Southern Levant comprised a network of semi-autonomous city-states under the formal jurisdiction of the New Kingdom of Egypt. The urban nodes prospered as the Mediterranean exchange network increased in size and intensity, with Cyprus standing out as the hub of this network, which gradually penetrated inland to form a link with the emerging Arabian trade (Bauer 1998:162-3). This restructuring, which took place in the 12th century, served as a basis for the emergence of the Phoenicians in the 11 th century and the considerable boom in trade also explains the appearance of the unified monarchy of Israel, in order to exploit the economic possibilities of its location between three of the major routes of the time, and also to oppose the threatening control of Egypt (Bauer 1998: 162-3). The first Phoenician route connected its bases in Levant with Egypt, with its vessels even entering the Nile as far as the port of Memphis. The height of Phoenician prosperity took place between 1200 and 700 BC. Although a number of peoples from the east (Babylonians, Assyrians, etc) gradually dominated these cities, they still continued to be major maritime trading centres. Around 800, the Phoenician expansion started to give shape to its principal routes towards the western Mediterranean, partly in response to the demand for Iberian silver and other metals, although trade was not restricted to this and also included slaves, wine, olive oil, etc. On the western side of the sea, their bases were at Utica, Malta, Cadiz and, above all, Carthage, which would soon become independent and would become a power in itself (Curtin 1984: 76). At around this time, following the decline of Egypt, the Phoenicians also controlled the maritime traffic in the Red Sea (Hourani 1995:8). A decisive moment occurred when the area around the Aegean Sea, after a period of much internal turbulence, re-entered the commercial world of the Mediterranean at around 800 BC. In the 5th century BC, the rise of Greek culture (occurring in the Aegean area as a result of the exchange of ideas, products and persons moving along the routes which converged at the Levant) led to the establishment of a series of crosscultural or ecumenical trade practices which spread right along the eastern Mediterranean coast. In this way, the slow work of centuries, developed by the different trade diasporas, gradually opened up areas of intercommunication which initially were merely commercial and then, with the expansion of the Greek language and culture, became homogenized (Curtin 1984:77, 80-1, 88).

Attention should be drawn to the role played by the Empire of Alexander (334-323 BC), which, despite its short duration, was to have long-lasting consequences. On the one hand, it spread the influence of Greek culture into the heart of Asia (with even a "Greek" empire in the north of India), making this culture prestigious and causing Greek to become an international (commercial and diplomatic) language. On the other hand, from the point of view of the Silk Road, for the first time the Aegean civilisation was firmly and permanently connected with the area of central and western Asia (including Egypt). In this way, these regional circuits were incorporated into a larger area. Now only China needed to be connected, in order to create the Great Silk Road, which would cross Asia from east to west.

Map 4. The Empire of Alexander the Great (334-323 BC)

Source: Igor Filibi

In the western Mediterranean, the same thing occurred with Latin and the Roman culture, completing the homogenization of a trading area created long before by the Phoenicians up to Carthage. In this way, it can be seen how the regional areas were gradually consolidated thanks to the activities of the traders and the empires, and how these areas, over time, extended in size to culminate firstly in Alexander's empire in central Asia and then with Mediterranean world of the Roman empire and the first great Chinese empire of the Han. And finally, these great partial areas united as links in the same trans-continental trading chain: namely the Silk Road.

All these routes and their variants, over the millennia, and their problematical unions and datings, appear to be clearer thanks to the interesting synthesis made by David Christian. This author, starting from the work of Frank and Gills (1993), upholds that the exchange networks crossing Eurasia from east to west are much older than was actually thought and that, in particular, those routes termed the "Silk Roads" are nothing more than the routes which interconnected the great agrarian civilisations. Christian suggests that the exchange networks between the pastoral nomadic and semi-nomad societies were established much earlier, as were the contacts between these societies and the primitive agrarian societies, long before the direct inter-connection of the great agrarian empires. Therefore, the trans-ecological commerce (between pastoral and agrarian societies) is just as, if not more, important than the trans-civilizational exchanges (Egypt - Aegean - Mesopotamia - China - India). This claim is supported by extensive archaeological evidence, which reveals the intensity of the exchanges of objects, technologies and religious practices between the peoples of northern Europe and to the north of China, for many millennia, through the steppes. The domestication of horses (fourth millennium BC) was decisive in this process, giving these people a mobility which they obviously made good use of. Furthermore, Christian explains how, even after the emergence of the traditional Silk Road between China and the Roman Empire, these pastoral peoples continued to be decisive (Parthian and Kushan Empires) and even after the 16th century, when the Silk Road appears to have been abandoned in favour of the maritime routes controlled by the Europeans. Christian points out that it is not possible to talk of a decline, but of profound change in the route brought about by the expansion of the cultivated surface area to include areas in the steppe which historically had been inhabited by nomadic peoples. Even in these new conditions, the nomadic peoples successfully maintained their trade, by offering the agrarian peoples products that they needed and did not have. In short, this author is suggesting that there was a profound inter-relation and synergy between the lifestyles of two types of societies that were very different, yet economically complementary: the agrarian and pastoral societies (Christian 2000). Christian himself summarises his general argument: By 2000 B.C.E., this world-system linked two distinct systems of exchange: an embryonic system of trans-civilizational exchanges, whose hub was the cities of the Oxus civilization;

and an extensive and well-established system of exchanges within and beyond the Inner Eurasian steppes. All in all, it seems reasonable to conclude that by 2000 B.C.E. the network of exchanges we know as the "Silk Roads" was already functioning as a system of vigorous and widespread exchanges within and sometimes beyond the Inner Eurasian steppes. And these early systems of exchange depended largely on the role of pastoralist communities.

Thus, “in reality, Han [Emperor] Wudi, like the Achaemenids and Macedonians before him, merely entered, by force, into already established systems of trans-Eurasian exchanges”. Or, more precisely, What really happened as a result of the conquests of Wudi, at the end of the second century, is that a new branch of the Silk Roads was created. This bypassed the older routes, through the steppelands of Xiongnu-controlled Mongolia. What is reflected in the written record, as in accounts of the sixth-century conquests of the Achaemenids, is really an attempt by agrarian empires to secure a greater degree of control over trade routes that had previously passed through the Inner Eurasian steppes, and had been dominated by pastoralist communities. (Christian 2000)

3. The phases of the Silk Routes

The works of Frank, Gills and Christian appear to be slowly convincing the scientific community. Recently, it has been pointed out that certain sections of the future Silk Road, responsible for the dissemination of persons, objects and ideas, started to function at least by the latter half of the third millennium BC, and intensified considerably in the second millennium BC. (Kuzmina 2008:118). In any case, although it is not precisely known when the regular trading of goods started between China and the Mediterranean, it is certain that there were contacts, although sporadic, around 500 BC, as this is when silk fabric started to appear in Europe. However, there is only evidence of regular trade from the Han dynasty onwards (202 BC - 220 AD). Given the fact that this piece of information come from official sources, it is certain that this marked the start of the trade protected by the States, however there were undoubtedly private commercial contacts long before this time. From that initial moment onwards, during the Han dynasty, various phases can be identified in the trading and activity along the Silk Road, at least as far as historical

evidence is concerned, and we shall now discuss these phases, following the lines established by Ma (1998). FIRST PHASE (1st century BC - 3rd century AD) In 138 BC, the emperor Wudi sent Zhang Chien, one of his trustworthy militiamen, on a mission to explore the western border with a view to establishing alliances to contain the barbarians in the north and to expand his empire. Thanks to the information gained from these expeditions, China expanded westwards in around 120 BC, for the purpose of obtaining some horses which were so well suited to war that the Chinese called them "heavenly horses" (being the only ones capable of halting the barbarians in the north). A further aim was to establish bases for trading with rich, developed areas such as the Sogdiana and Bactria regions. This Chinese expansion completed the network of ancient routes connecting the Mediterranean with Sogdiana, making it possible to trade not only with Central Asia but also with the distant Roman Empire. A number of official delegations were sent between both empires and trade agreements were established, giving rise to the Silk Road. Map 5. The Silk Road (3rd Century AD)

We would highlight the interrelationship between the different routes which formed part of a single trading system. Such that the intensification of the overland conflicts between the two major centralised empires (Persian and Roman) brought about an increase in maritime trade in the Persian Gulf. (Daryaee 2003). The Silk Road enjoyed a period of splendour up to the fall of the Han dynasty (220 AD) which was followed by the end of the Parthian empire (227 AD). Then the Kushan empire collapsed (330 AD) and, finally, the Roman empire. The stability guaranteed by these four powers, along the thousands of kilometres covered by the route (map 5), was replaced by a period of major political fragmentation. From that time onwards, the intensity of traffic on the route depended, amongst other factors, on the ability of the Chinese governors to control their north-western border, with the crucial Pamir mountain pass and the Tarim basin, the door of central Asia (Ma 1998). The cyclical problems to guarantee contact between China and central Asia served to strengthen trade between Persia and Byzantium, which were capable of maintaining powerful empires, particularly from the time when silk technology spread to these regions, around the 6th century. SECOND PHASE (7th - 8th century AD) The 7th and 8th centuries, the first two centuries of the Tang dynasty (618 - 960 AD) correspond to the second period of prosperity of the road, with the expansion of China westwards and the establishment of new oasis settlements along the route. This period was also marked by the rise and expansion of Islam. Year 751 represented a turning point in the period of Chinese hegemony, with a decisive Muslim victory over the Chinese army at the battle of the river Talas, which limited the Chinese influence in Central Asia and opened this region up to the expansion of Islam. In the opinion of Debin Ma, this battle led to a profound change in the silk trade. On the one hand, it led to the weakening of the Chinese empire, a process which would partially close the route for almost four centuries, until the era of the Mongol empire, due to the migration of the inhabitants from the western territories towards the Yangtze River valley and coastal regions. This meant that the major silk producing centres moved away from Xian, the starting point of the old silk route, and towards to the coast, leading to increased used of the sea route. On the other hand, in the battle of the river Talas, the Arabs captured many Chinese prisoners and obtained access to the silk cultivation technology, which they widely diffused through Asia towards

Persia, Anatolia and regions controlled by Byzantium. The conquest of the Sassanid empire and parts of the Byzantine empire allowed Islam to absorb the major silk producing regions and to spread sericulture technology to North Africa and Southern Spain. In this way, two different commercial circuits were created: Chinese silk controlled the markets of Japan, Southeast Asia and certain parts of Central and Southern Asia, whilst Persian silk principally supplied the Middle East, Europe and North Africa (Ma 1998). THIRD PHASE (12th - 14th centuries AD) The emergence of the Mongol empire of Genghis Khan (1167-1227), to create the largest empire ever to have been seen, led to the political unification of almost all of Eurasia. The Mongol rulers were concerned about the safety of the trade routes, leading to the construction of forts and enhanced infrastructures, they also introduced paper money and eliminated artificial trade barriers. This all led to a revival of the overland route as a whole. The Mongol empire started to collapse by the mid-fourteenth century, whilst in China the Ming dynasty had begun (1368 - 1644), a dynasty which was not able to maintain such a forcible control of the forever problematical North-western territories. Due to this cyclic instability, until the 16th century, trade with central Asia and the Middle East alternated between periods of much activity and periods in which trade was interrupted. FOURTH PHASE (17th - 18th century) As usual, the absence of powerful empires capable of ensuring stability and safety along the route threatened its continuity. For this reason, the establishment of the powerful, centralised Manchurian Qing empire (1644 - 1911) brought effective stability to the North-eastern territories (Ma 1998). The silk road was more stable at its western end, given the fact that the vacuum left by the collapse of the Mongol empire was quickly filled by the expansion of the Ottoman empire in the 14th century, in its concern to guarantee trade in a period in which Persia was becoming the most important silk producer and exporter, placing the Ottoman power in an ideal strategic situation for controlling this trade. These centuries witnessed yet another division of the work, with Persia as the major producer of raw silk, which was then processed by centres in Southern Europe and Syria. In this way, the trading circuit started in Persia and the silk was basically

transported by overland caravans which, on occasions, were combined with the use of the Black Sea, Persian Gulf and Red Sea, to its destinations in the Mediterranean. These routes were maintained until the mid-eighteenth century, until the end of the Safavid Persian state.

4. The end of the Mediterranean area and the creation of new areas The prominent historian on the end of the Roman world and the start of the Middle Ages was Henri Pirenne. Although some of his ideas have now been transcended by time, his overall view is still valid today. 1) Firstly, the unity of the Roman Empire was replaced by a plurality of States. Although "the appearance of Europe was changing, the fundamental character of its life remained the same" because these States are "merely fragments of the great unity that they had replaced. There was no profound transformation except in Britain" (Pirenne 2008:196-7). Translating this into the spatial language of Lefebvre (1974) we could say that the spatial complexity of the Roman world was replaced by a complex series of overlapping spaces and that, as a whole, they maintained continuity in commerce, in a number of legal and monetary spheres, etc. Although the political coherence that maintained the unity of this spatial complexity was lost, even without its co-ordinating bodies, the inertia of the Roman unity continued and this situation was to persist from the 5th to the 8th century (Pirenne 2008: 196-7). At the end of the 6th century, trade with the East took on considerable importance, and, due to their use in daily life, emphasis was on "the importation of spices. One cannot insist too strongly on their importance. The Roman Empire had already received all types of spices from India, Arabia, and China. It was the trade in spices that had built up the prosperity of Palmyra and Apamea (…). Their diffusion throughout the Roman Empire was not interrupted by the invasions, and continued afterwards, forming part of the everyday diet.” (Pirenne 2008:77). 2) Secondly, given the fact that, as has been seen, the Mediterranean unit survived the fall of Rome, the turning point was marked by the Moslem expansion. Islam split the Mediterranean in two, North and South, taking over the African coast and the Levant, and controlling maritime communications with the exception of the Aegean Sea and the Eastern coast of Italy as far as Venice. This divided the Christian Mediterranean into two basins, a western basin, blockaded, and another eastern basin, which was able to

maintain its sea connections. Therefore, the old Roman world was divided into three distinct spaces: a) Islam, b) the West, and c), the East.

a) Islam Pirenne pointed out that the "Christian Mediterranean was divided into two basins: The East and the West, surrounded by Islamic countries". This was the geo-political constraint for Christianity. The salient point is that the Moslem countries "the war of conquest having come to an end by the close of the 9 th century, constituted a world apart, self-sufficing and gravitating toward Baghdad". It was towards this central point that the caravans of Asia made their way and here ended the great trade route which led to the Baltic, by way of the Volga. It was from Baghdad that products were exported to Africa and Spain. The Moslems themselves did not trade with the Christians, but they did not close their ports to the latter. They allowed them to frequent their harbours, to bring them slaves and timber, and to carry away whatever they chose to buy." (Pirenne 2008:154-5, my italics). The consolidation of Islam was responsible for breaking with the old world, by creating a new "world", a new space which was completely separated from the former one: in terms of politics, religion and culture. However, in the same way that the fall of Rome did not signify the end of the Mediterranean economic unit, neither did the invasion by Islam imply the end of the long-standing trade between East and West. The Muslims merely controlled it and improved some aspects of it, however, above all, they tried to maintain it. This is probably the principal structural cause to account for the survival of Islam throughout the centuries. From a global point of view, the Muslim expansion almost appears to follow the Road towards the source of the silk and spices, reaching China and South-east Asia, as far as Indonesia and the Philippines.

b) The West In the North, the former Empire, which had already been divided into two de facto sections for some time, formalised the division with the coming of Charlemagne and the creation of the Carolingian pole. Byzantium was unable to prevent this division and both empires made this situation official in 812, when the emperor of Byzantium recognised the new power but in exchange for the return of the city of Venice and the south of Italy. This consolidated two spaces within Christianity. On the one hand, the Carolingian Empire in the west, isolated, land-locked, and therefore with no contact

with the great Eastern trade 3, restricted to an agricultural economy and, being extremely weak, would collapse and would shortly be the mark of the Middle Ages (Pirenne 2008:196-7).

c) The East On the other hand, the Byzantium Empire, in the east, was upheld as a Mediterranean and commercial power. It was the link between the Christian world and the East. Only Byzantium withstood Islam and maintained maritime trade between Venice, Southern Italy, the Adriatic coast and the Aegean Sea. Furthermore, once the period of expansion had passed, Moslem prosperity attracted Italian vessels to its ports, allowing them to connect to the Eastern routes (Pirenne 2008:154-5). Despite the fact that Byzantium withstood the Moslem siege in 719 and maintained control of the eastern part of the Mediterranean, the Moslem advances greatly limited the emperor's sphere of action On the one hand, the Italian cities which resisted (Naples, Gaeta, Amalfi, Salerno, Bari, Venice) "continued to recognise the emperor of Constantinople, but with increasingly weaker political ties" Furthermore, "with the Norman conquest of Italy and Sicily (1029 - 1091) the empire lost control of that region". With things as they were, "Venice, located at the dead end of the Adriatic sea, remained as a strategic Byzantine enclave, and as a result the Basileus (emperor) granted this merchant city much autonomy and allowed it to gradually become an independent republic". This was no more than the consequence of the imperial dependence on Venetian vessels which "supplied the enormous market of Constantinople, with close on a million inhabitants, and returned loaded with silks and spices" (Pirenne 1986:19).

d) Northern Europe This division into three distinct spaces, proposed by Pirenne, can be completed with the work of Wickham, who suggested the existence of a fourth space in the north of Europe (Wickham 2009:1174). In point of fact, Pirenne himself, when indicating the division of the Christian Mediterranean into two basins (East and West), surrounded by the 3

In point of fact, "from the 8th century onwards, western Europe experienced three hundred years of separation from all "overseas" countries, which signified (with few exceptions, such as Flanders) "an almost total interruption of trade (…), the disappearance of industrial activity and monetary circulation" (Pirenne 1995:72). The best indicator of this situation was that, from the end of the 7th century and early 8th century, spices disappeared from everyday food and were only to reappear from the 12th century onwards, with the re-opening of the sea. (Pirenne 2008:145).

countries of Islam, also mentioned in passing how this Northern Europe was able to connect Bagdad, the heart of Islam, with the Baltic Sea by way of the Volga river (the old amber route) and, from there, to export the products from the caravans of Asia, through France and Spain (Pirenne 2008:154-5). This would therefore be a fourth space, which was also connected to the Silk Road.

3) Thirdly, the Crusades marked a new stage for the Mediterranean end of the Silk Road, with the withdrawal of the Moslems and the gradual rise of the Italian merchant cities. The first crusade, initiated in 1096, retook control of the Tyrrhenian Sea and established Christian posts at Antioch, Jerusalem, St John of Acre and a number of enclaves along the Syrian coast. The Italian cities of Pisa, Genoa and Venice took the opportunity to secure advantageous conditions in trade with the Levant.

4

From that

time onwards “communications were re-established in all this essentially European sea” and “the conquest of the strategic isles of Cerdeña (1022), Corsica (1091) and Sicily (1058 - 1090) put an end to the Moslem control of the routes”. Pirenne pointed out that, despite the subsequent Turkish and Moslem counter-attacks in Christian territories, "The new offensive of Islam extended only to the mainland. The Turks had no fleet and did not attempt to create one. Far from harming them, Italian trade on the coasts of Asia Minor was to their advantage, for by it the spices brought by the caravans of China and India to Syria continued to be carried to the West by Italian ships. Nothing could have been more profitable than the persistence of a navigation which served to maintain the economic activity of the Turkish and Mongolian lands.". (Pirenne 1986:29-30)

4) Fourthly, the emergence of the Fairs marked a European economic boom. Pirenne observed that “The Fairs arose with the re-birth of commerce” and indicated that their origin “had nothing to do with the small local markets which by the beginning of the ninth century were appearing in ever increasing number over the whole of Europe.” Very different from the markets established for the purpose of supplying the provisions necessary for daily life to the local population, “fairs are periodic meeting places of professional merchants, centred on wholesale exchange” This was a new phenomenon 4

These cities were very well positioned, given the fact that during the Middle Ages in Europe, trade with the East and the redistribution of the products brought from the Levant was dominated by Genoa and Venice. Venice already frequented the ports of Egypt and Palestine before year 1000 and Genoa was present at least from 1065 onwards, although the city's development was due to the first Crusade (1095 1099). Venice organised important official expeditions which returned from the ports of the East principally loaded with spices (Feliu 1988:690-1).

which arose in the 11th century, increased in the 12th century and continued to develop in the 13th. The most active ones, the famous "Champagne and Brie fairs" are located more or less half-way along the great trading route which runs from Italy and Provence to the coast of Flanders". In the early 14th century, fairs started to decline as merchants became more sedentary and with the development of direct shipping links between the ports of Italy and Flanders and England (Pirenne 1986:75-7, 80). In this way, with the Italian cities leading the way, the European routes were connected, as an extension, to those linking West with East.

5. The re-incorporation of Western Europe into the long distance trading chain (11th - 14th centuries).

Increased European prosperity was brought about by its re-incorporation into long distance trade and, most importantly, into the great routes coming from the East and controlled by the Moslems. The cities of Italy, particularly Venice and Genoa, were primarily responsible for this re-incorporation. In the mid-twelfth century, Genoa saw its considerable efforts rewarded, when it achieved a stable position on the Levant coast and started to move inland towards Aleppo and Damascus. Furthermore, over the following decades, Genoa changed from purchasing eastern products with gold and silver to increasingly selling in the Levant, textile products produced in France, England and Flanders (Byrne 1920:212, 215-6), becoming a leading international distributor and export centre. In the 13th century there existed a series of sub-systems or spaces (defined as sharing a language, religion or empire) dominated by cities or imperial courts, which acted as centres. What is of interest here is that their respective interactions, although not as intense as present day ones, defined the outlines of a wider system. These 13th century sub-systems were more self-sufficient than present day regional systems and, therefore, depended less on each other for survival. Following this scheme, Abu Lughod has identified eight inter-locking sub-systems which, in turn, can be grouped or condensed into three key circuits: Western Europe, the Middle East and the Far East (Abu-Lughod, 1989:33) (map 6).

Map 6. Trading circuits of 13th Century

Source: Abu-Lughod, 1989:34

i) Description of the trading circuits Abu-Lughod points to the growing importance of a European "centre" formed by the Fairs of Champagne, the cities of Flanders and the ports of Italy, which acted as a real trading circuit or network. A key aspect of this European centre was the communications network with the exterior, and which connected the European subsystem with the more general system of exchanges. For this reason, this circuit cannot be understood without framing it in the Mediterranean system which, in turn, served as an interface with the general system. At this point, a major economic - political actor emerged: the city states of northern Italy, particularly Venice and Genoa. These Italian merchant towns were the ones to maintain, after the fall of the Roman empire, the small umbilical cord of trade that prevented the complete disappearance of commerce in Europe and upheld its only trading link with the East. From the 12 th and 13th centuries onwards, slowly and laboriously, these merchants managed to establish a connection with the three principal terminuses of the great trading route with the East (China, India).

Firstly, they established trading posts in the Black Sea, connecting Constantinople to China over the old Silk Road, which passed through the key nodes of Tabriz, Bukhara and Samarkand. This important overland route re-emerged primarily after the unification of Central Asia by the Mongols and, in particular, when the Mongols managed to conquer China itself.5 Secondly, the Crusader kingdoms along the Palestine coast enabled the Europeans to access a fourth sub-system that went overland as far as Baghdad, where the Route split into two branches, one going north-east to join the Central Asian caravan circuit and the other going south to access the Indian Ocean via the Persian Gulf. Thirdly and finally, the Europeans, principally the Italians, attempted to establish a third beachhead on the North-African coast at Egypt, at the port of Alexandria. However, after the crusade of St Luis in 1250, they had to resign themselves to a very limited trade as a result of the control exercised by the Egyptian rulers. This allowed the Italians solely indirect access to the fifth sub-system connecting Egypt with the Indian Ocean through the Red Sea (Abu-Luhod, 1989:35-36).

ii) Gradual incorporation of Europe into the great current of exchanges and key role played by the city states of Northern Italy: Venice and Genoa. Chaudhuri identified a general trend, by which “the port-towns and caravan cities which acted as commercial emporia in the trans-continental traffic of Asia prospered and declined in a pendulum motion of long-term cycles”. Likewise, the fortunes of the groups of merchants varied through time, depending on whether they were able to extend the routes or whether they were forced to give the routes up. In this way, in the 11th and 12th centuries the Jewish communities settled in Cairo and Alexandria and were as active in trade in the Indian Ocean as the Arab merchants on the Red Sea. With the approach of the 13th century, the Mediterranean group disappeared. The Christian European merchants (Greeks, Genoese, Venetians and Catalans) were to be found in all the major ports of the Levant, and played a key role in the development of trade in the Mediterranean and also in the Atlantic, “but they did not, and were not allowed to, venture beyond Suez or Aleppo in the period before the Portuguese discovery of the

5

Although it appears that the safety of the route beyond Trebisond, was never fully guaranteed, the Italian merchants never stopped trying to establish advance posts and even a castle on the outskirts of Tabriz. For an overview of these many attempts, Vid. Kedar 1981:187-90.

Cape route.” For their part, the great merchant families of Southern China regularly faced serious political impediments which prevented them from maintaining or increasing their trade with India and beyond. Chaudhuri observed that, after 1433 these Chinese merchants were no longer seen in Calicut or in any other Indian port, although they continued to be as active as ever in the internal Chinese market, which cannot do without them. However, it is significant that “Chinese junks still sailed to Malacca, to the numerous islands of the Java Sea, to Manila, but not to India, the Red Sea, or East Africa. The explanation remains elusive.” (Chaudhuri 2005:99-100). However, Lo already demonstrated in 1958 that Ming China experienced a profound economic crisis in the mid-fifteenth century, which could go a long way to explaining the Chinese withdrawal from the Indian Ocean. Based on this work, Abu-Lughod, in her magnificent book Before European hegemony, offers quite a plausible explanation on the new restrictive policies of the Ming dynasty. To do so, she goes back to the Mongol invasion of China, which already brought great changes with it. Firstly, the reunification of North and South China under the Yuan dynasty. Secondly, the new regime complemented the Chinese internal economy, which was basically agricultural, with two systems of foreign trade which acted synergically. On the one hand the revived "Silk Road" crossing Central Asia and ending at Peking. On the other hand, the Indian Ocean trade route which ended at Canton, Zaytun and, less importantly, at Hangchow. “Thus, China constituted a crucial link between the land and sea trades and, in her domain of influence at least, became a formidable power in an increasingly integrated world system.” The causes for the fall of the Yuan dynasty included the succession of plagues and other epidemics which devastated China from 1313 to 1368, when the very demographically weakened Mongols lost power to the Ming dynasty. Therefore the Mings inherited a China which, although unified, was in a highly delicate geo-political situation given the fact that, in addition to the deaths caused by the epidemics devastating the production and commercial centres of the South, Tamerlan had closed the overland Silk Road which ended in Peking. The Indian Ocean maritime road was still in operation, however, despite the efforts to revive it, trade in the Indian Ocean was also declining. Faced with this situation, Ming China, with no resources to continue to maintain its political and commercial ambitions across the seas, decided to withdraw and concentrate on the reconstruction of its agrarian base and on domestic production. Paradoxically, “what is viewed in Chinese history as a restoration of a legitimate dynasty must be viewed in world system perspective as the final fragmentation of the

larger circuit of thirteenth-century world trade in which China had played such an important role” (Abu-Lughod 1989:342, 346-7, 345). Abu-Lughod summarizes the argument pointing out that China‟s geographic position in the thirteenth century world system was crucial because it linked the northern overland route with the equally if not more important Indian Ocean sea route. When both of these pathways of trade were fully functioning, and particularly when China was unified and could therefore serve as a “frictionless exchange medium” to connect them, the circuit of world trade was complete. Indeed, it was only when this circle was completed in the thirteenth and early fourteenth centuries that one could speak of a premodern “world system”. As was true in other subregions of that world system, the economic health of China rested primarily on (...) her ability to harness her local resources. But another part of her economic vitality (...) came from her ability to extract surplus from the external system. When the external system underwent retrenchment and fragmentation, it was inevitable that all parts formerly linked to it would experience difficulties, including China. (Abu-Lughod 1989:348)

With the two routes blocked (the Central Asian one was closed and the maritime one was declining rapidly) from the late 14th century and through the entire 15th century, the only remaining contact between Europe and Asia was the one maintained between the Venetians and Egyptians with their marriage of convenience, strengthened by the lack of alternative routes.6 Thus, “the “Fall of the East” preceded the “Rise of the West”, and it was this devolution of the preexisting system that facilitated Europe‟s easy conquest” (Abu-Lughod 1989:360-1).

6. The Silk Road as a product of the "long term”

The history of this ancient unit, which is the Mediterranean, "has frequently been determined by the triumph of a route, a city, at the expenses of another route and another city, even in the 16th century, when everything appeared to belong, although it did not yet belong to the great Empires and to the territorial States” (Braudel 1980:368). 6

In 1370, Tamerlan started the reconstruction of the Mongol empire. In 1395 he plundered the Genoese colony of Tana in the Crimea and, in 1401 Damascus, taking many of the city's artisans into inland Asia. After his death (1405) the empire was torn apart by internal wars which definitively ruined central Asia and severed the contacts with China. The steppes route practically disappeared, in prelude to the collapse of the Byzantine Empire (1453). These events led to increased activity on the southern routes through Damascus and Egypt, which remained the sole contacts with Eastern trade (Feliu 1988:699).

Fernand Braudel, with his innovative subject-matter of study, a "sea" instead of the habitual "national territories", radically questioned the traditional way of analysing societies and their different spheres. The space in question was not any of the current States, many of which either did not yet exist or had different borders from their present ones, but the Mediterranean space as a whole. In turn, within this area, the routes are the principal explanatory factors: on each route, "the commerce, cities and States either decline or prosper with it", without forgetting that "all goods, material and immaterial, flowed into the cities along the routes", therefore these communications "are the infrastructure of all coherent history" (Braudel 1980:418-9). The importance given to flows, to communication channels between specific "nodes", represents something like a nervous system which gives orders and reacts to stimuli or a blood system which constantly feeds and keeps the whole of the unit alive, in this case a spatial unit. These metaphors suggest two constituent aspects of social reality, two sides of the same coin: an active network which focuses on command, supply and protection nodes; and a space which the elites controlling these routes (particularly the most important routes, the long distance trade routes) try to impose so that, from some nerve centres, they can reach out to all relevant places (mines, markets, strategic passes, etc) that do not control other alternative centres, or which are governed by weak centres and, therefore, become opportunities for commercial or military conquest (and often both). In our opinion, although social space appears to be something static and state-run, its true nature is dynamic (adaptable) and it is opposed to being captured in unchanging territories or with fixed boundaries (a precise "inside" that is opposed to an equally specific "outside") as national States try to appear (Walker 1993; Agnew 1994). Space is, therefore, a dynamic duality, space / network. To understand the logic of a specific social space it is necessary to understand which networks (economic, political, social, religious etc) are involved in its construction. This is a key point, given that "(social) space is a (social) product" (Lefebvre 1974:35). The fact that space is constructed implies interests, which are generally diverse, and therefore each particular space is generally contested. This is the first element of complexity. The second consists in the overlapping of different spatialities and which can at times be complementary but are very often contradictory and cause conflicts. The complexity of (social) space shows that, although space is generally considered in the singular, it would be more correct, from an analytical point of view, to distinguish the various overlapping spaces. Although merely for analytical purposes, since actual space

is multilayered and inseparable. The spatial unit, which can be compared to a flaky pastry cake [millefeuille], is the real object. The overlapping of religious, linguistic, political spaces etc., shapes social spatiality at any given time. The Mediterranean unit was based on "religion, language and the remains of the Roman occupation" which caused "the European population to be culturally more homogeneous than any other area in the world, with the exception of China" (Tilly 1992:24). It was precisely religion (Islam) that also caused the former Roman - Mediterranean space to take different historical directions, to the north and to the south (Pirenne). Braudel made an important contribution by pointing out the existence of a number of temporal rhythms. In the same way as space is multi-layered and complex (Lefebvre), time can be broken down into a number of rhythms, depending on the phenomenon or process that is to be analysed (Braudel). There is a fast rhythm, very close to the surface, rapidly changing and which hardly affects anything deeper down. A second, intermediate term rhythm, makes it possible to distinguish a specific period having a certain internal coherence (i.e. the Cold War) from the vast historical continuum. However, here it is interesting to focus on a third, deeper level, which the French master termed "long term" (longue durée). Here time appears to stand still, unless observed from the perspective of centuries. Few phenomena can withstand this level of analysis. Like a sieve, the longue durée perspective filters all the millions of small events, the hundreds of relevant events in each century and, finally, like gold nuggets, we are able to view a very small number of elements that remain almost unchangeable, from one century to another. Only this long term perspective makes it possible to capture, in all its grandeur, the constant flow of gold and silver, first from the Mediterranean and later from America, always towards the East, advancing along the thousands of stopping points on the Silk Road to invariably end up in China. It could be said that the Silk Road is a product of the longue durée. It is not contradictory to affirm, on the one hand, that the routes and social spaces are variable and constantly adapting, whilst, on the other hand, pointing to the continuity of the Silk Road over more than two millennia. The reason is that routes tend to remain in use for long periods of time, which is undoubtedly a result of the stable structure of the landscape. However the density of routes does change through time, as materials and people flow in different amounts at different times (Wilkinson 2009). Likewise, the Silk

Road is not a single route, but various routes (although not just any route) which, when available, compete and lower the prices and earnings and, when one of the routes is blocked or transit is difficult, then the flow of caravans with their merchandise is immediately redirected towards the alternatives available. This is a historical constant of the Silk Road or, more exactly, of the network of routes making up the Silk Road: when China is unable to control the passes in the northeast, then the maritime route takes on greater prominence, which reaches the same destination but passes through the Indian Ocean; when the Red Sea or Strait of Malacca are plagued with pirates, then the silk returns to the mountain passes in the Pamirs, to the oases of Turfan, passing through Samarkand and Bukhara. In addition to silk, new products have gradually appeared over time: cotton, tea, spices, etc. However, observed from the perspective of centuries, these routes have remained virtually unchanged. In this respect, we can say that the Silk Road is a product of the long term.

Geographical continuity is the most important structural element sustaining the continuity of the routes. Only a truly exceptional event would alter this, such as a radical climate change or the desiccation of a great inner sea. Likewise, the discovery of a new route, either as a result of new technology, or because the political and economic conditions required to open it are fulfilled (circumnavigation of Africa), or due to the discovery of a new continent (America), can also affect the old routes. This is what happened between the late 15th century and early 16th centuries.

7. The new Silk Routes in an "extended world”

The late 13th and early 14th centuries witnessed the entry of Genoese galleons into the Atlantic to avoid the overland route crossing France and which was no longer safe and profitable. With the progressive decline of the Champagne Fairs, the Genoese became increasingly more involved in the Atlantic, reacting to the changes in the European economic sub-system. Subsequently, the closure of the Central Asian route and the de facto monopoly held by Venice on the Alexandria route, forced the Genoese to seek other alternatives. The expulsion of the Moslems from Andalusia in the second half of the 15th century during the Christian reconquest, meant that the ports of the Straits of Gibraltar were now safe, giving definitive access to the Atlantic. Therefore, the

Genoese, backed by the material resources of the Portuguese and Spanish States, set out to explore the vast ocean and to seek direct routes to China and the spice islands. The accidental "discovery" of America and the incorporation of this "New World" into the now "Old World", marked the start of the process to construct a truly global economy, involving a structural change which would differentiate the ancient world from the modern “World-System” (Abu-Lughod 1989:362-3) The Portuguese expansion commenced in 1415 with the conquest of the Moslem trading port of Ceuta. In 1487-8 Bartolomeu Dias bordered the Cape of Good Hope to open the doors of the Indian Ocean to the Portuguese crown and give direct access to the Spice Islands (Moluccas). Venice, and the Spanish crown, were equally concerned about these new developments. At that time, Spain was trying to find a direct route across the Atlantic to the Spice Islands, before Portugal. Christopher Columbus set sail with the intention of achieving this sole objective and, in 1492, he accidentally came across a new continent: America. There was intense competition to see who would finally achieve control of the spice trade: Venice, Portugal or Spain. The Portuguese burst violently into the Indian Ocean, putting an end to a long era of pacific trade and freedom at sea. From 1500 to 1515 they rapidly took control of the best ports to the east of Africa, Malabar, Konkan, the Persian Gulf and the strategic Strait of Malacca. From 1515 to 1560, “the viceroyalty of Goa reached the height of its sea-power and was able to enforce a semi-monopoly in the pepper and spice trade”. From 1560 to 1600, the Portuguese were unable to maintain the situation and, due to the maritime power of the north Sumatran Sultanate in Acheh, they failed to prevent a revival of the spice trade through the Red Sea and the Mediterranean. Furthermore, in this period, the government of Goa, the important Portuguese base in the Indian Ocean, established a commercial network with the ports of Macao, Nagasaki and the Philippines, which was more profitable than the pepper monopoly (Chaudhuri 2005:66). The Spanish were quick to respond. The initial voyages to the Caribbean were followed by a whole series of expeditions, in an attempt to get round the new continent and discover the way to the Far East. In 1513, Vasco Nuñez de Balboa discovered the "Southern Sea" (Pacific Ocean). In 1519 Magallanes set sail to try and find a direct route to the spices and, three years later, the vessel Victoria returned to Spain, captained by Elcano, having made the first round-the-world journey.

At around this time, in 1521, Legazpi founded Manila, initiating direct trade with the Spanish crown and East Asia, however the decisive moment occurred in 1565, when the Basque explorers, Legazpi and Urdaneta, discovered the "Tornaviaje", the winds and currents which made it possible to return from Manila (Philippines) to the west coast of America (Acapulco). From that moment onwards, it was possible to travel from America to the South-east Asian islands and then return with merchandise to America and then send it on to Spain across the Atlantic. In 1573 direct trade started between Spain and China, through the exchange of gifts, including silks and spices, a trade which was to last 242 years (Ponce Aguilar 2002: 93). The whole world was finally connected. Here lies the origins of global unification, achieved through the routes which would progressively create a single world economy (Braudel 1980: 1985) and, from the 18th century onwards, a World-System (Wallerstein 1976). The age of the European empires (first the Portuguese and Spanish, then the Dutch, English and French) could be understood to represent a new phase in the Silk Road. However, we are dealing with a different Route, given the fact that the old Euro-Asian routes now had to adapt to the circumstances of an "extended world" to which the American continent had been added. As has already been discussed, when the Asian overland route was blocked, the Maritime route through the Indian Ocean immediately became more popular, now there were even more options, with the option of a new route crossing the Pacific to reach America, and go on to Europe. Since the early 16th century, the Spanish had been trying to open a canal through Central America, aware that this would alter the world geo-political situation, although this was only made possible in the 20th century. Likewise, the Pharaohs tried to open a canal in Suez, although this too was only achieved last century. These two passages led to the rethinking of the maritime routes, as the relative costs of some routes were reduced to the detriment of others. With regard to the overland routes, these did not disappear when the European empires gained control over the control of the seas. The other actors reacted and tried to seek alternatives. In the mid-seventeenth century, the Manchurian Qing Empire (1644 1911) finally managed to stabilise the North-east pass and the great traditional route started to re-open. And safety was once more fully ensured with Tsarist Russia in the 18th century and early 19th century, when the tsars extended their influence towards the east. From that time onwards, the route underwent a change of direction, due to the fact that the silks from the Yangtze river were taken northwards and reached the north of

Central Asia through Siberia, territories under Russian control. The northern caravan route gained importance over the old route thanks to this complete safety guaranteed by the Chinese and Russian empires, which made it possible to even reach Europe without leaving the territory controlled by the tsars (Ma 1998). The following phase of the overland Silk Road occurred when, following the NorthAmerican example, the tsars managed to link both ends of their empire, through the Trans-Siberian railway. This colossal route finally displaced the older route, which was further south, and established Russian influence in Central Asia up to these present times. The Asian "Great Game" was adversely affected and Russia was consolidated to the detriment of Great Britain and the Ottoman Empire. In the beginning of the 20th Century an analyst observed the decisive Russian move and pointed out that “trans-continental railways are now transmuting the conditions of landpower, and no where can they have such effect as in the closed heartland of Euro-Asia, in vast areas of which neither timber nor accessible stone was available for roadmaking.” (Mackinder 1998:30) To end this brief review of the European - Asian routes, over the millennia, mention should be made of the "new routes" which transport the equivalent of silk or spices in our times: petrol and gas flowing through the immense oil and gas pipelines from the deposits in Central Asia, which some of the largest available in the world, to the global markets. Yet again, Russia was the one to push forward with the construction of these infrastructures, when the Central Asian republics were part of the Soviet Union. At present, any geo-political analysis must primarily take account of two factors: the end of the Cold War and the rise of South-east Asia (Arrighi 2003). Spatialities change and discourses should follow suit. At the fall of the Soviet Union, the new Russian State was obliged to re-define its priorities. After a transitional period, in which official discourse indicated the need to re-unite with western civilisation, Russia has repositioned itself on the geo-political scene with a discourse which emphasises that it is part of the Euro-Asian space, its own sphere of civilisation which is neither European nor Asian (Smith 1999). There is no doubt that geo-politics is “a discursive practice by which intellectuals of statecraft „spatialize‟ international politics in such a way as to represent it as a „world‟ characterized by particular types of places, peoples and dramas.” The connection between geo-politics and national identity is also well established. In this way, in the same way as geopolitics, “national identity is moulded by political elites and does not exist separated from political discourse and competition

and, for this reason can not be static or eternal (Zevelev 2001; Bashkirova 2003; Khasanova 2004).” (O‟Loughlin et al 2005:322).

The main alternative to the Russian oil pipelines is the TRACECA project, which is directed at extracting petroleum from the Black Sea region through an east - west axis, passing through Georgia and Turkey. This plan has already experienced an opposing action with the project to complete the North - South axis to connect the north of Europe with Russia, Iran and to reach the coast of the Indian Ocean, from where it could be taken to India by boat. The boom experienced by South-east Asia, in particular China and India, and the growing demands made by these countries for the limited energy resources, put a new (energy based) Silk Road scenario at the centre of global geopolitics. This framework alone will make it possible to put the still recent intervention of Russia in Ossetia into context. In this same way, the North-American military operations in Iraq or Afghanistan and the threats to Iran, place this region yet again at the heart of international relations. If all this is taken into account, the precedent geo-political definition takes on its full meaning: “a discursive practice by which intellectuals of statecraft „spatialize‟ international politics in such a way as to represent it as a „world‟ characterized by particular types of places, peoples and dramas.”

References Agnew, John (1994), “The territorial trap: the geographical assumptions of interna tional relations theory”, Review of International Political Economy, 1/1; pp. 53-80. Arrighi, Giovanni (2003), “The rise of East Asia and the withering away of the interstate system”, in: Brenner, Neil et al (eds.). State / Space. A reader. Oxford, Blackwell; pp. 131-146. Bauer, Alexander A. (1998), “Cities of the sea: Maritime trade and the origin of Philistine settlement in the early Iron Age southern Levant”, Oxford Journal of Archaeology 17(2); pp. 149-168. Blázquez Martínez, José María (1981), “Dura-Europos. Enclave comercial sobre el Éufrates”, Revista de Arqueología 9, pp.27-34. Braudel, Fernand (1980). El Mediterráneo y el mundo mediterráneo en la época de Felipe II. México..., Fondo de Cultura Económica, 2 tomos; tomo 1. Braudel, Fernand (1985). La dinámica del capitalismo. Madrid, Alianza.

Bravo Jiménez, Salvador (2009), “El estrecho de Gibraltar en la antigüedad. Un análisis desde

la

literatura

periegética”,

Almoraina.

Revista

de

Estudios

Campogibraltareños, nº 38, abril; pp. 27-44. Brenner, Neil (1999), “Beyond state-centrism? Space, territoriality, and geographical scale in globalization studies”, Theory and Society, 28; pp. 39-78. Byrne, Eugene H., “Genoese trade with Syria”, The American Historical Review, Vol. 25, No. 2, 1920, pp. 191-219. Carbó, Juan Ramón and Hidalgo, María José (2008), “El ecumenismo romano en época de Trajano: espacios de inclusión y exclusión”, Stud. Hist., Hª antig. 26; pp. 63-86. Carter, R.A. (2001), “Saar and its external relations: new evidence for interaction between Bahrain and Gujarat during the early second millennium BC”, Arabian Archaeology and epigraphy 12; pp. 183-201. Carter, Robert (2003), “Tracing Bronze Age trade in the Arabian Gulf: Evidence for the way-stations of the merchants of Dilmun between Bahrain and the Northern Emirates”, in: Potts, Daniel; Al Naboodah, Hasan and Hellyer, Peter (Eds.). Archaeology of the United Arab Emirates. London, Trident Press; pp. 124-130. Carter, Robert (2006), “Boat remains and maritime trade in the Persian Gulf during the sixth and fifth millennia BC”, Antiquity, 80; pp. 52-63. Chaudhuri, K.N. (2005 [1985]). Trade and civilisation in the Indian Ocean. An economic history from the rise of Islam to 1750. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. Christian, David (2000), “Silk Roads or Steppe Roads? The Silk Roads in World History”, Journal of World History 11.1; pp. 1-26. Curtin, Philip D. (1998 [1984]). Cross-Cultural Trade. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. Daryaee, Touraj (2003), “The Persian Gulf trade in late antiquity”, Journal of World History, Vol. 14, No. 1, March; pp. 1-16. Domínguez Pérez, Juan Carlos (2006), “Estructuras comerciales romanas en el período pre-anibálico: una lectura crítica interdisciplinar del período medio-republicano”, Gerión 24; pp. 179-194. Dussel, Enrique (2002), “World-System and “Trans”-Modernity”, Nepantla: Views from the South 3.2; pp. 221-244. Edens, Christopher (1992), “Dynamics of trade in the Ancient Mesopotamian „World System‟”, American Anthropologist, Vol. 94, No. 1; pp. 118-139.

Feliu, Gaspar (1988), “El comercio catalán con oriente”, Revista de Historia Económica, Año VI, nº 3; pp. 689-707. Flammini, Roxana (2005), El antiguo Estado egipcio como alteridad: cosmovisión, discurso y prácticas sociales (ca. 3000-1800 a.C.)”, Iberia, nº 8; pp. 9-26. Franck, Andre Gunder (1998). ReOrient: Global Economy in the Asian Age. Berkeley, University of California Press. Franck, Andre Gunder y Gills, Barry K., eds (1993). The World System: Five Hundred Years or Five Thousand? London and New York, Routledge. González-Tablas Nieto, Javier (2010), “La explotación de recursos en los márgenes del valle del Nilo durante el Reino Medio: la Dinastía XII”, El futuro del Pasado. Revista Electrónica de Historia, nº 1; pp. 237-248. Höllmann, Thomas (2008). La Ruta de la Seda. Madrid, Alianza. Hourani, George F. (1995). Arab seafaring in the Indian Ocean in ancient and early medieval times. Princeton, Princeton University Press. Kedar, Benjiamin Z. (1981 [1976]). Mercanti in crisi. A genova e Venezia nel ‘300. Roma, Jouvence. Krueger, Michal (2008), “Valor, prestigio e intercambio. Los métodos ante la teoría”, Herakleion, nº 1; pp. 7-19. Kuzmina, Elena Efimovna (2008). Prehistory of the Silk Road. Philadelphia, University of Pennsylvania Press. Larsen, Mogens Trolle (1987), “Commercial networks in the Ancient Near East”, in: Rowlands, Michael; Larsen, Mogens and Kristiansen, Kristian. Centre and periphery in the ancient world. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press; pp. 47-56. Ma, Debin (1998), “The Great Silk Exchange: How the world was connected and developed”, in: Flynn, D.; Frost, L. and Latham, A.J.H. (eds). Pacific Centuries: Pacific and Pacific Rim History since the 16th Century. Latham, Routledge. Mackinder, Halford (1998), “The geographical pivot of history (1904)”, en: Dalby, S.; Ó Tuathail, G.; and Routledge, P. (eds). The Geopolitics reader. London, Routledge; pp. 26-31. Marfoe, Leon (1987), “Cedar forest to silver mountain: social change and the development of long-distance trade in early Near Eastern societies”, in: Rowlands, Michael; Larsen, Mogens and Kristiansen, Kristian. Centre and periphery in the ancient world. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.

Mernissi, Fátima (2007). El miedo a la modernidad: Islam y democracia. Madrid, Ediciones del Oriente y Mediterráneo. Murphy,

Susana

B.

(2000),

“Modernidad,

imperialismo,

globalización,

mundialización...”, X Congreso Internacional de la Asociación Latino-Americana de Estudios Africanos y Asiáticos (Río de Janeiro). O‟Loughlin, John; Ó Tuathail, Gearóid and Kolossov, Vladimir (2005), “Russian geopolitical culture and public opinion: the masks of Proteus revisited”, Transactions, Institute British Geographers, 30; pp. 322-335. Ó Tuathail, Gearóid and Agnew, John (1992), “Geopolitics and discourse: Practical geopolitical reasoning in American foreign policy”, Political Geography, Vol. 11, 2, March; pp. 190-204. Phillips, Jacke (1997), “Punt and Aksum: Egypt and the horn of Africa”, Journal of African History, 38; pp. 423-457. Pirenne, Henri (1986). Historia económica y social de la Edad Media. México, Fondo de Cultura Económica. Pirenne, Henri (1995). Historia de Europa. Desde las invasiones al siglo XVI. México, Fondo de Cultura Económica. Pirenne, Henri (2007). Las ciudades de la Edad Media. Madrid, Alianza. Ponce Aguilar, Antonio (2002). Historia de Baja California. De cueva pintada a la modernidad. Renfrew, C. (1975), “Trade as action at a distance: questions of integration and communication”, in J. Sabloff & C.C. Lamberg-Karlovsky (ed.) Ancient civilization and trade: 3-59. Albuquerque, NM: University of New Mexico Press. Ruiz Martínez, Apen (1997), “Los fenicios en Málaga: un estudio sobre los encuentros culturales en la antigüedad (VIII-VI a.n.e)”, Cuadernos de Arqueología Mediterránea, tomo 3; pp. 47-68. Sanz Roche, Esteban (2001), “Los habitantes del Sáhara en la antigüedad”, Anaquel de Estudios Árabes 12; pp. 671-685. Scholte, Jan Aart (2000). Globalization: a critical introduction. London, Macmillan. Sherratt, Andrew (2004), 'Trade Routes: the Growth of Global Trade', ArchAtlas, February 2010, Edition 4, http://www.archatlas.org/Trade/Trade.php, Accessed: 16 July 2010. Smith, G. (1999), “The masks of Proteus: Russia, geopolitical shift and the new Eurasianism”, Transactions, Institute of British Geographers, 24; pp. 481-500.

Tilly, Charles (1992). Coerción, capital y los Estados europeos, 990-1990. Madrid, Alianza. Toby Wilkinson (2009), 'Pathways and highways: routes in Bronze Age Eurasia', ArchAtlas,

February

2010,

Edition

4,

http://www.archatlas.org/workshop09/works09-wilkinson.php, Accessed: 16 July 2010. Voutsaki,

Sandra (1992),

“Value and

exchange

in pre-monetary societies.

Anthropological debates and Aegean archaeology”, Hydra, 10; pp. 42-53. Walker, R.B.J. (1993). Inside/Outside: International Relations as Political Theory. New York, Cambridge University Press. Wallerstein, Immanuel (1976). The modern World-System: Capitalist agriculture and the origins of the European World-Economy in the Sixteenth Century. New York, Academic Press. Wilkinson, David (2002), “The status of the Far Eastern Civilization/World System: Evidence from city data”, Journal World-Systems Research, Vol. 8, No. 3; pp. 292328.